Skip to main content

Table of Contents

  1. Topic pack - Microeconomics - introduction
  2. 1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply
  3. 1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply - notes
  4. 1.1 Competitive markets - questions
  5. 1.1 Competitive markets - simulations and activities
  6. 1.2 Elasticities
  7. 1.2 Elasticities - notes
  8. Section 1.2 Elasticities - questions
  9. Section 1.2 Elasticities - simulations and activities
  10. 1.3 Government intervention
  11. 1.3 Government Intervention - notes
  12. 1.3 Government intervention - questions
  13. 1.3 Government intervention - simulations and activities
  14. 1.4 Market failure
  15. 1.4 Market failure - notes
    1. The meaning of externalities
    2. Types of externalities
    3. How do externalities affect allocative efficiency?
    4. Negative externalities of production
    5. Negative externalities of consumption
    6. The economic theory of traffic congestion
    7. Demerit goods
    8. Government responses - demerit goods
    9. Possible government responses to externalities
    10. Direct government provision
    11. Extension of property rights
    12. Taxes and subsidies
    13. Tradeable pollution rights
    14. Regulation, legislation and direct controls
    15. Positive externalities of production
    16. Positive externalities of consumption
    17. Merit goods
    18. Why might merit goods be underprovided by the market?
    19. Government responses - merit goods
    20. Public goods
    21. Common access resources & sustainability
    22. The tragedy of the Commons
    23. Common access resources in practice
    24. Sustainability
    25. Threats to Sustainability
    26. The threat to sustainability from the use of fossil fuels
    27. The threat to sustainability from poverty
    28. Government responses to threats to sustainability
    29. Cap and Trade Schemes
    30. Promoting Clean Technologies
    31. The 'dirty side' of cleaner technologies
    32. International responses to threats to sustainability
    33. Asymmetric information
    34. Abuse of monopoly power
    35. Inequality
  16. Section 1.4 Market failure - questions
  17. Section 1.4 Market failure - simulations and activities
  18. 1.5 Theory of the firm
  19. 1.5 Theory of the firm - notes (HL only)
  20. Section 1.5 Theory of the firm - questions
  21. Section 1.5 Theory of the firm - simulations and activities
  22. Print View

Possible government responses to the under-provision of merit goods

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\government_legal.jpgSyllabus: Evaluate, using diagrams, the use of government responses including:

  • subsidies,
  • legislation,
  • advertising to influence behaviour, and
  • direct provision of goods and services.

In practice, governments play a substantial role in the provision of merit goods such as health and education, even where they are ideologically committed, as the Republicans are, to market forces. However, the exact form that such government involvement should take is a subject of much dispute, and we shall consider each of the following in turn:

  • direct government provision
  • regulation
  • subsidies
  • a combination of government provision and market forces

Direct government provision

There are certain adviantages to the idea of direct government provision of services such as healthcare and education:  There may be large economies of scale, leading to productive efficiency. On the other hand without competition direct provision can create inefficient bureaucratic organisations leading to waste of vaçluable resources.

The idea of universal provision for all on the basis of need, with prices and profits playing no role, is one which sits very uneasily with the philosophy of market economics, and has thus in recent years come under fierce attack from right-wing, market-oriented economists. They have argued that government provision of health and education has led to an undesirable situation of state monopoly power in these areas and that to increase consumer choice, lower costs and raise the level of efficiency, greater competition is required.

Research and understand what Obamacare is in this context.

Legislation and Regulation

The government may also use a range of regulations both to increase the consumption of merit goods and to ensure good quality provision. In the case of education, it may be compulsory that all children between the ages of 5-16 receive some form of schooling, be it in the private or public sector, and quality is controlled in such ways as school teachers being required to have stipulated qualifications before they are allowed to teach.

In the case of health care, vaccinations against various contagious diseases could be made compulsory and medical practitioners such as doctors, dentists, opticians and nurses could be required to obtain certain qualifications before they can practice. The government could also use regulation to enforce the consumption of a good provided by the private sector which is deemed to be a merit good by virtue of the positive externalities that it generates: the compulsory consumption of seat-belts by motorists provides one such example.

In the case of housing, the use of rent controls on private sector rented accommodation are a means by which the market can be regulated so as to protect tenants from having to pay high rents.

Rent controls represent a form of price fixing. More specifically, they represent an attempt to fix a maximum price below the equilibrium i.e. a maximum rent that a private landlord may charge for rented accommodation; and, to be effective, rent controls may also have to be accompanied by further regulation preventing the landlord from ousting the tenant once the rent has been fixed. Figure 1 below illustrates the fixing of such a maximum, and the possible longer term problems

rent_control

Figure 1 The use of rent controls

The diagram shows that, with a relatively inelastic supply of rented accommodation, the free market rent would be established at a price of OP, with the quantity demanded and supplied equal at OQ. However, if the government impose a ceiling of OP1 on the price that landlords can charge, an initial shortage of Q1Q2 develops as the short term profitability of renting-out accommodation declines. In the longer term , if landlords' rate of return falls below what they could receive from alternative investments, such as government bonds, then existing landlords could be expected to leave the housing market with little new rented accommodation coming onto it. As a consequence, the supply of rented accommodation would shift from S to S1, and the shortage would increase to Q3Q2. Thus, unless the government could shift the supply curve to the right, for example by building more publicly owned council houses, the long term shortage would worsen, with the existing rent-controlled stock descending into an ever greater state of disrepair, as a result of landlords seeking to reduce their costs by postponing or cancelling repair and maintenance work.

Subsidies

Subsidies may be used to increase the production and consumption of merit goods.

For example, the theatre is usually provided by the private sector, and is often regarded as a merit good on account of the educative and civilising benefits that it confers on society. The government might take the view that without state assistance to the arts, there would be an unacceptably small number of theatres able to survive. Figure 2 illustrates how the subsidy would operate.

merit_subsidy

Figure 2 The effect of subsidising a merit good

In the diagram, the free market price of theatre tickets is established by the intersection of the curves D and S at OP, with the equilibrium quantity at OQ. A government subsidy, equivalent to the vertical distance XY, would have the effect of shifting the supply curve to the right, causing the market price to fall to OP1 and the quantity of theatre tickets demanded and supplied to increase to OQ1. Consumers' expenditure on the theatre increases from OPZQ to OP1YQ1 and the area P1RXY represents the total amount that the government spends on the subsidy.

In the case of health care in several West European countries, the majority of it is provided free to the user out of general taxation, although charges may be levied for prescriptions and optical and dental treatment. In these cases the prices charged have been made cheaper than they would otherwise be, with patients only paying part of the cost of treatment and the government making up the difference through the payment of subsidies to suppliers. In the case of housing, owner occupiers receive a subsidy through the receipt of tax relief on mortgage interest repayments, which is not available to those people who rent their accommodation. State education like health care, may be provided without direct charges being made, although education vouchers represent an alternative form of market-based, subsidised provision which has been proposed.

For a subsidy to work effectively, the government would have to assess the value of the marginal external benefit (i.e. the positive externality) to society and give a subsidy equivalent to this amount.


eg

If the good in question were solar panels (on housing) which confer benefits on society in terms of energy conservation, households prepared to install solar panelling could be given a grant, and this would shift the demand curve D=PMB to the right to D1=SMB. Allocative efficiency is achieved as SMB = SMC at OQ1. A similar result could be achieved by subsidising the output of solar panels which would cause the supply curve to shift to the right until the socially optimum level of production is reached.

ext_pos_cons_1

Figure 3 Positive externalities - Solar Panels