Skip to main content

Topic pack - Microeconomics - introduction

Welcome to this Triple A Learning topic pack for Microeconomics. The pack has a wide range of materials including notes, questions, activities and simulations.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\source_files\micro2.png

A few words about Navigation

So that you can move to the next page in these notes more easily, each page has navigation tools in a bar at the top and the bottom. These tools are shown below.


The right arrow at the top or bottom of the page will take you to the next page of content.


The left arrow at the top or bottom of the page will take you to the previous page.


The home button will take you back to the table of contents for the pack.

The pack is split into a series of sections and to access each section, the easiest way is to use the table of contents on the left-hand side of the page. To return to the full table of contents, please click on the 'home button' at any stage.

Higher level extension material

Some of the material in this pack relates to the higher level extension topics in the Business and Management guide. This material is marked by icons as follows:

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gif

This icon indicates the start of the higher level extension material.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

This icon indicates either:

  1. The higher level extension material continues on the next page or
  2. The higher level extension material continues from the previous page

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

This icon indicates the end of the higher level extension material.





To start viewing the contents of the pack, please click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page.

Key terms - competitive markets

One of the key things you need to be sure to know are the definitions of all key microeconomics terms. In this section we give you explanations and definitions of terms relevant to competitive markets.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Key terms - elasticity

One of the key things you need to be sure to know are the definitions of all key microeconomics terms. In this section we give you explanations and definitions of terms relevant to elasticity.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Key terms - government intervention

One of the key things you need to be sure to know are the definitions of all key microeconomics terms. In this section we give you explanations and definitions of terms relevant to government intervention.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Key terms - market failure

One of the key things you need to be sure to know are the definitions of all key microeconomics terms. In this section we give you explanations and definitions of terms relevant to market failure.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Key terms - theory of firm

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\HL.gif

One of the key things you need to be sure to know are the definitions of all key microeconomics terms. In this section we give you explanations and definitions of terms relevant to theory of the firm.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Aims of the economics course

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\source_files\micro1.png

The aims of the economics course at HL and SL are to enable students to:

Assessment Objectives

Having followed the economics course at HL or SL, students will be expected to:

  1. AO1 Demonstrate knowledge and understanding of specified content
    • Demonstrate knowledge and understanding of the common SL/HL syllabus
    • Demonstrate knowledge and understanding of current economic issues and data
    • At HL only: Demonstrate knowledge and understanding of the higher level extension topics
  2. AO2 Demonstrate application and analysis of knowledge and understanding
    • Apply economic concepts and theories to real-world situations
    • Identify and interpret economic data
    • Demonstrate the extent to which economic information is used effectively in particular contexts
    • At HL only: Demonstrate application and analysis of the extension topics
  3. AO3 Demonstrate synthesis and evaluation
    • Examine economic concepts and theories
    • Use economic concepts and examples to construct and present an argument
    • Discuss and evaluate economic information and theories
    • At HL only: Demonstrate economic synthesis and evaluation of the extension topics
  4. AO4 Select, use and apply a variety of appropriate skills and techniques
    • Produce well-structured written material, using appropriate economic terminology, within specified time limits
    • Use correctly labelled diagrams to help explain economic concepts and theories
    • Select, interpret and analyse appropriate extracts from the news media
    • Interpret appropriate data sets
    • At HL only: Use quantitative techniques to identify, explain and analyse economic relationships

Section One Structure

Unit one has four core sub-topics and one HL extension.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\source_files\Topic 1 Microeconomics.png

1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\core.gif

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply - notes

Introduction

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\market.jpgResources are allocated in competitive (free) markets through the workings of the price mechanism. Price changes give signals to suppliers who are able to respond to the demands of consumers. If the price of vegetables rises, for instance, more farmers will want to grow and sell (supply) vegetables. Also, if more people want to buy vegetables (demand) in an area, say as a result of increased population, prices will rise.

Two key terms have been mentioned, supply and demand. Write down now, before you go any further, what you think these terms mean. Put your descriptions to one side. We will return to them later.

The free market price mechanism, operating under certain specific conditions (more of this later) is also the base against which the workings of real markets and economies are measured by economists.

In this section we consider the following topics in detail:


This unit examines the concepts of demand and supply in detail, then goes on to examine the operation of a competitive market. It is an extremely important unit, not only in its own right, but also because it links in with other units, such as units 3 (International Economics) and 4 (Development Economics).

The nature of markets

So, what is a market?


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Market

A market is any effective arrangement for bringing buyers and sellers together, not necessarily face-to-face, to enable trade to take place.


The forces of supply and demand meet and react in a market. Prices are established and buyers and sellers alike give signals. Markets can involve face-to-face dealings between buyers and sellers, or may be postal or even electronic.

The market mechanism brings together two different forces, the power of the consumer and the interests of the supplier. Both want 'the best' from the market, but their 'bests' are different.

Objectives of consumers

Rational consumers want to get the most from their money and a RATIONAL CONSUMER wants the highest quality at the lowest price.

Objectives of producers

Firms want to get the maximum from the resources that they use. In financial terms they want to maximise profit. This means that they may want to sell as low a quality product as they can for as high a price as possible.

The general assumption of economics is that the main objective of private businesses is profit maximisation.

Types of markets


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Market structure

market_supermarket_shelvesIn a competitive market, firms are expected to compete. We have assumed so far in our market model that firms compete on price only. This is not the case in the real world. Firms may compete on the basis of:

as well as price.

The world of competition can be fierce and dynamic. Highly competitive firms continually try to improve their position in the market by producing better, more reliable goods and services, to ensure that they are providing products that are better than their rivals, for example. They ultimately want to increase their profit. They will look at their production processes and may try to reduce costs and to increase revenues.

They will only do this if they can get something from it, and that something is profit. Unless there is a financial return they will not invest in any improvements. Why should they?

Spectrum of competition


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

You may also like to see a table summarising each of these key market structures with examples. Don't worry too much about the column headed 'Demand curve for firm' as this will be fully explained in the study of demand.

Summary of market types

Demand

A detailed understanding of demand theory is essential for success in economics.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Demand

Demand is that quantity of a good or service that consumers are willing and able to buy at each and every price in a given period of time.


This means that demand combines:

This definition is important. The demand for something has to be what is known as effective demand. This means that the demand has to be backed by a willingness AND ability to pay. You might want to buy a Lamborghini car, but only if you are willing and able to pay for it can the demand be regarded as effective.

The law of demand


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Individual and market demand


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Non-price determinants of demand


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Movements along the demand curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:


nb

The demand curve is drawn on the assumption that only price has changed and everything else has remained the same. This is an important assumption to note. In reality many factors are changing at the same time, but if we are to analyse the factors causing a change in the market, we first need to isolate each of the factors. This assumption, known as 'ceteris paribus' or 'other things being equal' enables us to do this.

Shifts in the demand curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:


nb

The demand curve is drawn on the assumption that only price has changed and everything else has remained the same. This is an important assumption to note. In reality many factors are changing at the same time, but if we are to analyse the factors causing a change in the market, we first need to isolate each of the factors. This assumption, known as 'ceteris paribus' or 'other things being equal' enables us to do this.


Summary

Having completed this session you should know and understand that:

1. Effective demand is the quantity of a good that would be bought at each and every price over a period of time.
2. It combines the desire for the good with an ability and willingness to pay for it.
3. Demand has several determinants, e.g. own price, price of other goods, real income, changes in tastes and fashion, season and population.
4. A change in price results in a movement along an existing demand curve.
5. A change in any other factor, apart from price, will cause the entire demand curve to shift.

Example - shifts and movements along a demand curve

You must be absolutely certain about what causes shifts and movements along a demand curve. Work carefully through the following example.

eg

Example 1 - Movements along and shifts of demand curve

The diagram below, Figure 1, represents the demand for a product at a point in time. The price then was P*.

d_pq1

Figure 1 Demand curve

Copy this onto another piece of paper, then sketch on this new diagram the effect of the following changes. Treat each change as a separate change - in other words start each time from Figure 1. Once you have had a go at each one then follow the link below to check you got the change right.

(a) The firm launches a new, effective advertising campaign.

Answer - change (a)

(b) The market price of the product rises to P2.

Answer - change (b)

(c) The price of a substitute good is reduced.

Answer - part (c)

(d) The price of a good falls from P1 to P2.

Answer - part (d)

(e) The real incomes of the buyers of this desirable product increase significantly.

Answer - part (e)

(f) There is an increase in the population size and the size of the potential market.

Answer - part (f)

These should not be difficult if you keep calm. Ask yourself three questions:

Exceptions to the normal law of demand

We have assumed so far that demand curves slope downwards from left to right, and most of the time this is true. However, there are a few circumstances where it is possible for the demand curve to slope upwards to the right. This may be for the whole curve or, more likely, it may be over a certain price range, as shown in Figure 1. This is often termed a perverse or upward sloping demand curve.

d_perv

Figure 1 Perverse demand curve

There are two particular types of goods where this may occur and they are called Giffen goods and Veblen goods. Let's look at the definitions of these.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Giffen good

A Giffen good is a good for which an increase in price results in an increase in demand for the good. It is an extreme inferior good and will have a perverse (i.e. upward sloping) demand curve.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Veblen good

A Veblen good (named after an American economist - Thorstein Bunde Veblen) is a good that has an upward-sloping demand curve. People buy more of the good because it is more expensive and therefore demand is higher when the price is higher.


Giffen goods

In some poor countries, the people often live on a basic diet of rice which is very cheap plus a few more expensive vegetables or some much more expensive meat or fish. In such societies, if the price of rice rises then the people may well decide to buy more in order to substitute it for the more expensive vegetables and meat. There has been an increase in demand in response to an increase in price. Sir Robert Giffen fist noticed this phenomenon. In the 19th century, he saw that the demand for potatoes increased in response to the rises in the price of potatoes caused by the great potato famines in Ireland. Hence products of this kind are known as Giffen goods. Examples of Giffen goods are difficult to find in richer countries.

Veblen goods

Products such as perfumes, expensive cars, jewellery, works of art and designer clothes may be regarded as Veblen goods. With these products, a rise in price is often interpreted by the consumer as an increase in quality or ostentation and so they may decide to buy more, thinking that they are buying a superior product. There may be psychological factors at work. The economist Veblen carried out research into this and concluded that the price of a product conveyed more than just value information for the consumer; it also represented status and exclusivity. These products which appear to experience rising demand with rising price are known as Veblen goods.

The demand curve for such goods will slope upwards from left to right.

d_perv

Price expectations

It is also possible for goods where price expectations are critical to have perverse demand curves. This is because if people expect prices to increase further, then they may buy more now. In this case it appears that an increase in price has increased demand, but in reality this has come about because people expect prices to rise even further in the future.

Linear demand functions

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to understand linear demand functions and to be able to calculate demand and plot a demand curve from a demand function. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Linear demand functions

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Linear demand functions - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 100 - 8P

Using this demand function, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantity demanded for prices from $0 - $10.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand curve for the product.
  3. If the demand function changes to Qd = 100 - 10P, draw up a new table to show the change in quantity demanded for prices from $0 - $10.
  4. Plot the new demand curve.
  5. If the demand function now changes to Qd = 120 - 10P, draw up a new table to show the change in the values for quantity demanded for prices from $0 - $10.
  6. Plot this new demand curve.
  7. Explain two reasons for:
    1. the change in the demand function from Qd = 100 - 8P to Qd = 100 - 10P
    2. the change in the demand function from Qd = 100 - 10P to Qd = 120 - 10P

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

The law of supply

Supply

That quantity of goods and services that will be supplied to the market at various prices in a given time period.



If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Non-price determinants of supply


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Movements along the supply curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:


nb

The supply curve is drawn on the assumption that only price has changed and everything else has remained the same. This is an important assumption to note. In reality many factors are changing at the same time, but if we are to analyse the factors causing a change in the market, we first need to isolate each of the factors. This assumption, known as 'ceteris paribus' or 'other things being equal' enables us to do this.

Shifts in the supply curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:


nb

The supply curve is drawn on the assumption that only price has changed and everything else has remained the same. This is an important assumption to note. In reality many factors are changing at the same time, but if we are to analyse the factors causing a change in the market, we first need to isolate each of the factors. This assumption, known as 'ceteris paribus' or 'other things being equal' enables us to do this.

Shifts and moves of supply curve

You must be absolutely certain about what causes shifts along or movements of a supply curve. Work carefully through the following example.

eg

Example 1

The diagram below, Figure 1, represents the supply of a product (X) at a point in time. The price then was P1 and the quantity supplied Q1.

s_pq1

Figure 1 The supply of Product X

Copy this onto another piece of paper, then sketch on this new diagram the effect of the following changes. Treat each change as a separate change - in other words start each time from Figure 1. Once you have had a go at each one then follow the link below to check you got the change right.

(a) Market price of the product falls from P1 to P2.

Answer - part (a)

(b) The government passes new minimum wage legislation, which will have the effect of increasing the cost of labour to the firm (an increase in costs of production).

Answer - part (b)

(c) The government places a tax on the sale of the product.

Answer - part (c)

(d) A new and highly efficient production process has been developed for a good.

Answer - part (d)

(e) Producers in a market can easily produce two products - chocolate chip cookies and chocolate coated cookies. The market for chocolate coated cookies has considerably declined. Producers decide to supply more chocolate chip cookies to the market instead.

Answer - part (e)

This should not be too difficult if you keep calm. Ask yourself three questions:

The real supply curve?

The supply curve is usually drawn as an upwards (left to right) sloping curve. This implies that as price rises, so will the supply. This further supposes that the response time for the supplier is zero. In many cases this is far from the case. If it was, then supermarket shelves would never be out of stock of the item you want! Consider the market for houses in a region illustrated in Figure 1 below.

s_el_0_a

Figure 1 Supply of houses

Builders are constructing and selling 'Q' houses per month at present at price 'P'. Suddenly demand increases significantly, as a government department is moving a capital city office there. What can be done? Not much, at least in the next few months.

Supply is essentially fixed at Q, regardless of demand. The supply curve is a vertical line. Prices will be put up by the developers if they think it worthwhile - in our diagram prices have risen to P1.

housing_new_buildSupply will take time to react to the new situation. They need land and planning permission and this can take months or years to organise. It will then take anything from 6 months to a year to build the house itself.

Once adjusted, the builders will actually be operating on another vertical supply curve. They will now be building Q2 houses per month and the pressure on prices is eased (though the exact impact will depend on national effects as well). Let's hope the government does not change its mind!

s_el_0_b

Figure 2 Increase in supply

Now think about the supply of things like CIVIL AIRCRAFT, AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS and FOREIGN HOLIDAYS.


SUPPLY CHANGES SLOWLY, MUCH MORE SLOWLY THAN DEMAND.

Linear supply functions

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to understand linear supply functions and to be able to calculate supply and plot a supply curve from a supply function. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Linear supply functions

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Linear supply functions - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear supply function of the form:

Qs = -30 + 10P

Using this supply function, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantity supplied for prices from $4 - $15.
  2. Plot these figures to give the supply curve for the product.
  3. If the supply function changes to Qs = -30 + 12P, draw up a new table to show the change in quantity supplied for prices from $4 - $15.
  4. Plot the new supply curve.
  5. If the supply function now changes to Qs = -50 + 12P, draw up a new table to show the change in the values for quantity supplied for prices from $4 - $15.
  6. Plot this new supply curve.
  7. Explain two reasons for:
    1. the change in the supply function from Qs = -30 + 10P to Qs = -30 + 12P
    2. the change in the supply function from Qs = -30 + 12P to Qs = -50 + 12P

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Market equilibrium

In the previous section we explained markets and the rules of supply and demand. We now move on to examine market equilibrium, the price mechanism and market efficiency.

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\core.gif.

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Market equilibrium - notes


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Excess demand and excess supply


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Changes in demand and supply

We can now see how shifts of supply and demand curves cause changes in prices and quantities bought and sold. In the next two pages, there are two example markets with a series of changes to each. Try working through each one and check that you understand how the curves shift. Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to look at the first example.


Summary

Having worked through this unit you should be able to:

1. Define a market
2. Show how it responds to changes in supply and demand
3. Demonstrate that movements along a demand curve come as a result of a shift in the supply curve, and movements along a supply curve from a shift of the demand curve.

Example 1 - the market for DVD players

eg

Copy out Figure 1 below and label it as the market for DVD players.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\ds_pq1.gif

Figure 1. The demand and supply model of a market

Now work through the following changes, and adjust the diagram as you go. After you have had a go at each change, follow the answer link below and see if you made the right changes. Treat each change as a separate change - in other words start with Figure 1 each time.

Change 1. The development of a new microchip enables producers to reduce the price of their products.

Change 1 - answer

Change 2. A major and successful advertising campaign is mounted for DVD's.

Change 2 - answer

Change 3. The government applies VAT (sales tax) to all home entertainment equipment.

Change 3 - answer

Example 2 - the market for fish

eg

fish01Let's look at another example, and make sure that you understand how the shifts and movements occur and interact. Now work through the following changes, and adjust the diagram as you go. After you have had a go at each change, follow the answer link below and see if you made the right changes.

Figure 1 represents the market for fish at the start of a week. Assume that all demand and supply changes occur without delay, i.e. they react instantly. The changes given are all sequential. In other words use the diagram you end up with as the starting point for the next change.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\ds_pq1.gif

Figure 1 The Market for fish

Change 1. There are very rough seas and small boats cannot fish.

Change 1 - answer

Change 2. It is Thursday, a day where the demand for fish is very high. Seas become even rougher and even fewer boats can go to sea.

Change 2 - answer

Change 3. It is Friday, when demand for fish is even higher. Storms weaken, though, and fishing becomes easier.

Change 3 - answer

In this example, we have seen price rises accompanied by an increase in sales. This does not mean that the rules of price and demand are wrong, just that in such cases there will have been changes in the determinants, other than price, of supply and demand. Be careful to separate shifts from movements. Notice that movements along a demand curve come as the result of movements (shifts) of supply.

Applications of demand and supply

Markets rarely react fast, so it takes time for the market to regain equilibrium after it has experienced a change or a shock. Examine Figure 1, which shows the effect of an increase in demand on the market for new houses in an area. Assume that a major, large government department has just announced that it is to relocate to this area.

ds_ex3

Figure 1 The market for new houses

The initial market was defined by demand curve D and supply curve S. The market was in equilibrium at price P1 when Q1 new houses were bought and sold. The entry of the government department will increase demand and shift the demand curve to D1. Supply will take time to react so price will rise initially to P2, then fall back slowly to P3 as the supply of houses increases. It will move from one equilibrium position, P1Q1, to another, P3Q2, over a period of time. It will pass through P2Q1 on the way.

Further examples are the markets for drugs or alcohol. Suppose the police were to really crack down on drug dealing, with considerable but not perfect effect. What would happen?

The US Government once tried to ban the sale, and hence consumption, of alcohol in America, but with only partial success. What happened here? Look at Figure 2.

ds_ex4

Figure 2 The drug or alcohol market

In both cases the measures had no effect on demand, but reduced supply. So price would go up but the quantity available would fall.

For the drugs, the street price would be an indication of the success of the police. The greater the rise, the greater the degree of success.

Calculating market equilibrium

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to understand how to calculate market equilibrium from demand and supply functions. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Calculating market equilibrium

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating equilibrium - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 85 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -20 + 10P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $2 - $12.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.
  3. Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.
  4. If the demand function changes to Qd = 100 - 5P, draw up a new table to show the change in quantity demanded for prices from $2 - $12.
  5. Plot the new demand curve on the original demand and supply diagram.
  6. Using simultaneous equations calculate the new equilibrium price and quantity.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Scarcity and choice


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Choice and opportunity cost

When you make a choice to buy something you exchange cash for a product or service. For most people, cash is relatively scarce. So this choice means that spending the cash on means that it cannot be used to buy something else. This introduces the concept of opportunity cost.


Opportunity cost

The opportunity cost of an activity is the sacrifice made to do it. It is the real cost of the next best alternative foregone when an economic decision is made. The more a nation produces of one thing, the less of something else it can produce. The sacrifice of the alternative is the opportunity cost.


A few examples:

  1. The government choose to spend more on health care. This may mean sacrifices elsewhere and may mean less spent on affordable housing. The reduction in housing is the opportunity cost.
  2. The opportunity cost of working overtime (supplying more labour) is the leisure time that you have sacrificed.
  3. You own a lawnmower that you rarely use. It has a second hand value of $50. The opportunity cost of keeping the mower is $50.
  4. You are given $400 as an 18th birthday present. You decide to spend it on a holiday rather than put it into a long - term saving account. The opportunity cost of the holiday is the savings that have been given up.
  5. You buy a CD instead of purchasing lunches for a week. The opportunity cost of the CD is the lunches given up.

The fact that there is an opportunity cost to every transaction means that we all face trade-offs in the decisions we make. As a society, we cannot have everything we want and so to have more of one thing, we may have to have less of another. This notion of trade-offs is one that will recur throughout your economics course. It will also arise when we look at the management of the national economy as governments face trade-offs as well as individuals. They may want low unemployment and low inflation, but less of one may mean more of the other.

Remember, however, that opportunity cost is not a financial cost - it is a resource cost, i.e. what's given up in real, as opposed to money terms.

Price signalling

Resource allocation - the importance of price as a signal

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Signalling function

In a market economy, prices perform a signalling function - prices adjust to show where resources are required and where they are not.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Incentive function

Prices also perform an incentive function. As prices rise or fall, this provides an incentive for producers to increase/reduce supply (as profitability of the good changes) and an incentive for consumers to purchase less/more (as the benefit they receive falls/rises).


S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\dollar_symbol.jpgThe central problem of economics is one of scarcity of productive resources relative to the unlimited potential demand that could be made upon them. It therefore follows that every society, be it centrally planned or based upon markets, has to have some mechanism (system) by which its resources, that is its land, labour and capital, are allocated amongst all the numerous uses to which they could be put. So, by what process are resources deployed so as to ensure that consumers obtain exactly the right amounts of frying pans, ice creams, jeans etc. that they require? Well, under a system of central planning the answer is not too difficult to ascertain - the state planning authority decides upon its priorities and directs resources to those lines of production which are deemed to be most important; but, in the absence of a central planning authority, how do consumers magically obtain those goods that they want in just the right quantities? Here the answer is slightly less obvious - essentially, it is through the interaction of demand and supply. How exactly does this interaction perform the allocative function?

The short answer to the above question is that it is through movements in prices. These changes in price indicate and motivate - this is called the signalling function. Changes in price indicate the relative strength of consumer demand and signal to producers the changes in demand for their goods or services. Prices also indicate changes in supply that enable producers to signal to consumers what is available on the market and on what terms. Rising prices of goods motivate producers to respond to increases in demand by increasing supply; producers will decrease supply when prices fall. You will see more clearly how this works when you see how the market forces of supply and demand interact to determine price.

Market efficiency - consumer surplus


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Market efficiency - producer surplus


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Allocative efficiency

Allocative efficiency is an important concept in economics and one we shall return to throughout this module. Allocative efficiency is essentially a situation where consumers are getting the maximum possible satisfaction from the current combination of goods and services being produced and sold. In other words by changing their pattern of consumption and buying different quantities of goods and services, consumers could not increase the satisfaction they are getting.

If we apply this concept at the level of a market, then we can see that society will get the maximum possible benefit when a market is in equilibrium. If we look at figure 1 below, then we can see that at a quantity of Q* (the equilibrium quantity), both consumer and producer surplus are maximised. If the economy was to produce a quantity below Q*, then more consumer and more producer surplus could be gained by a greater quantity being produced and sold of this good.

ps_cs_f

Figure 1 Consumer and producer surplus

Allocative efficiency requires two different types of efficiency:

  1. Efficiency in consumption - this is where consumers allocate their incomes in such a way that they get the maximum possible satisfaction from their limited incomes. We assume that this is what all rational consumers are trying to achieve.
  2. Efficiency in specialisation and exchange - this type of efficiency requires efficient markets where firms specialise in producing and selling and consumers specialise in working so that they can buy goods and services. In this way the markets are as efficient as is possible.

The combination of both these types of efficiency results in allocative efficiency. Allocative efficiency will be increased as long as doing more of something results in a greater marginal benefit to society than marginal cost. As long as this process continues, allocative efficiency will increase. The optimum level of allocative efficiency will be where this process reaches its logical conclusion. In other words where marginal benefit = marginal cost.

1.1 Competitive markets - questions

In this section are a series of questions on the topic - competitive markets. The questions may include various types of questions. For example:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to work through the questions.

Market structures - self-test questions

question

1

Market structures

Match the following descriptions with the appropriate market structure?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not quite right. Try again.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Market structures

Which of the following is the most competitive market structure?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, well done.No, this is fairly competitive but not the most competitive.No, this is where a few firms only dominate the market.No, this is the least competitive.
Check your answer

3

Market structures

Which of the following is the least competitive market structure?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, this is the most competitive.No, this is fairly competitive.No, this is where a few firms only dominate the market.Yes, well done.
Check your answer

4

Market structures

Which of the following is NOT a feature of monopolistic competition?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, this is a feature. Although the firms are competing against each other, in monopolistic competition there is sufficient differentiation so as to view each firm as almost a monopoly for their own product.No, this is a feature. Although the firms are competing against each other, in monopolistic competition there is sufficient differentiation so as to view each firm as almost a monopoly for their own product.No, this is a feature. Although the firms are competing against each other, in monopolistic competition there is sufficient differentiation so as to view each firm as almost a monopoly for their own product.Yes, this is not a feature - products are assumed to be differentiated. Although the firms are competing against each other, in monopolistic competition there is sufficient differentiation so as to view each firm as almost a monopoly for their own product.
Check your answer

5

Market structures

In which form of market structure would price be the key factor when competing?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, there will be NO competition for the firm here.No, the few firms in this industry can also compete in non-price competition.No, firms will also compete through product differentiation. Yes, all products appear the same which means price becomes a crucial factor in competition. In perfect competition, there are many firms selling homogenous products. Prices are driven down to the same level.
Check your answer

Market structure - short answer

question

Question 1

Discuss three different ways that firms can compete.

Question 2

Why do firms do research?

Question 3

Distinguish between short run and long run advantages to a firm of competition.

Question 4

Distinguish between short run and long run advantages to a consumer of competition.

Question 5

What is the driving force behind the research done by firms?

Price as a signal - short answer

question

The importance of price as a signal

Question 1

Explain how the price mechanism assists in the allocation of resources

Question 2

Discuss the case for and against doctors charging patients for their services

Demand - self-test questions

question

1

Demand

Which of the following would be likely to decrease the demand for a product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is likely to increase the demand. No, that's not right. This is likely to increase the demand.Yes, that's correct. This would normally lead to a reduction in demand. No, this is likely to increase the demand (so long as the good is a normal good).
Check your answer

2

Shift in demand curve

Which of the following may lead to a shift in the demand curve? (Select all possible correct responses)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
a) Yes, that's correct. An increase in cost will shift the supply curve and not the demand curve.a) No, that's not right. An increase in cost will shift the supply curve and not the demand curve.b) Yes, that's correct. An increase in income will shift the demand curve to the right.b) No, that's not right. An increase in income will shift the demand curve to the right.c) Yes, that's correct. A decrease in income will shift the demand curve to the left.c) No, that's not right. A decrease in income will shift the demand curve to the left.d) Yes, that's correct. An increase in price will lead to a move along the demand curve and not a shift.d) No, that's not right. An increase in price will lead to a move along the demand curve and not a shift.e) Yes, that's correct. An increase in the price of a substitute good will mean a shift in the demand curve to the right as people demand more of this good instead.e) No, that's not right. An increase in the price of a substitute good will mean a shift in the demand curve to the right as people demand more of this good instead.f) Yes, that's correct. A change in productivity will shift the supply curve and not the demand curve.f) No, that's not right. A change in productivity will shift the supply curve and not the demand curve.
Check your answer

3

Supply

Which of the following would be likely to shift the supply curve for Mars Bars to the left?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct. Cocoa is a raw material for Mars Bars and an increase in prices will therefore shift the supply curve to the left.No, that's not right. Cocoa is a raw material for Mars Bars and a change in prices will therefore shift the supply curve, but prices have increased and this will shift the supply curve to the left.No, that's not right. Changes in productivity will shift the supply curve, but as productivity has increased this will shift the supply curve to the right. No, that's not right. Changes in price will lead to a move along the supply curve.
Check your answer

4

Demand

Which of the following would be likely to lead to an extension in demand for iPods?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answer No, that's not right. The Sony player will be a substitute and will therefore lead to a shift in the demand curve to the left (if at all).No, that's not right. An increase in income will mean people have more purchasing power and will therefore lead to a shift in the demand curve to the right, not an extension.Yes, that's correct. Changes in productivity will shift the supply curve, and as productivity has increased this will shift the supply curve to the right. This will lead to a move along the demand curve to the right - an extension in demand.No, that's not right. Changes in costs will shift the supply curve, but as costs have increased this will shift the supply curve to the left. This will lead to a movement along the demand curve to the left - a contraction in demand.
Check your answer

Demand - short answer

question

Question 1

What is individual demand? What is the difference between individual demand and market demand?

Question 2

The table below represents the market for DVD's. For each of the changes given, tick the relevant column to show whether the demand curve has shifted either left or right or whether there has been an extension or contraction of demand (a movement along the demand curve).

Change Shift right Shift left Extension in demand Contraction in demand
There is an increase in real incomes
Raw material costs increase
New capital equipment enables DVD producers to increase productivity
A new super CD-ROM is developed that is cheaper than DVD's but has same functionality
A major pay per view cable provider goes into liquidation
There is a serious recession
Prices of DVD players fall


Question 3

d_right

Demand curve shifting right

Energy saving light bulbs can be used to replace conventional light bulbs. At present energy saving light bulbs are significantly more expensive to buy than normal light bulbs and the light takes several minutes to reach full intensity. If the above demand curve is the demand curve for energy saving light bulbs, which of the following events may have caused the shift shown?

(a) A fall in price of a conventional light bulbs
(b) Government legislation restricting the manufacture and sale of conventional light bulbs
(c) An increase in the cost of electricity
(d) An increase in the price of raw materials required for the manufacture of energy saving light bulbs
(e) Medical reports about cancer causing effects of energy light bulbs

(f) A decrease in real incomes
(g) An increase in real incomes
(h) A major advertising campaign showing the benefits of energy light bulbs
(i) Improved technology speeding up the time taken for energy saving light bulbs to reach full light intensity

Question 4

Which of the following would you regard as substitutes for a laptop computer and which may be complements? In each case consider whether they are 'close' complements or substitutes.

(a) Apple iPod

(b) Desktop computers
(c) PDA's
(d) Web site development software
(e) Mobile phones
(f) Handheld tablet computers
(g) Docking stations

Supply - short answer

question

Question 1

The table below represents the market for computers. For each of the changes given, tick the relevant column to show whether the supply curve has shifted either left or right or whether there has been an extension or contraction of supply (a move along the supply curve).

Change Shift right Shift left Extension in supply Contraction in supply
There is an increase in real incomes
A surplus of memory on world markets leads to a significant price fall for memory chips
New capital equipment enables computer producers to build machines cheaper
Labour costs for manufacture increase
There is agreement by G8 countries to put a tax on computers
Rapid growth in the developing world means increased demand for computers
The development of TV-based interactive internet services


Question 2

s_left

Supply curve shifting left

If the above supply curve is the supply curve for energy saving light bulbs, which of the following events may have caused the shift shown?

(a) A fall in price of a substitute for energy saving light bulbs
(b) A subsidy on the production of energy saving light bulbs
(c) A fall in labour costs for producing conventional light bulbs
(d) A fall in the price of raw materials required for manufacture
(e) Anticipating a increase in demand, major manufacturers invest in new capital equipment for the manufacturing of energy saving light bulbs
(f) A decrease in real incomes

Question 3

Which of the following is a reasonable explanation of the direct relationship between price and supply (the supply curve)? N.B. A number of them could be right.

(a) Improvements in technology help manufacturers to supply more at a lower price.
(b) As price of a good or service falls, firms will shift to producing other goods which become more profitable.
(c) At higher prices it is still profitable to use more expensive factors of production switched from other areas.
(d) At higher prices it is worthwhile producing more despite higher costs of production as the profit margin stays the same.
(e) Labour costs tend to increase each year.

Demand and supply - short answer

question

Interaction of demand and supply

Question 1

The data in the table below shows the demand and supply for digital cameras at various prices.

Price (£) Quantity demanded (millions per year) Quantity supplied (millions per year)
16 140 20
32 120 60
48 100 100
64 80 140
80 60 180


(a) Plot the demand and supply curves on a diagram.
(b) What would be the excess demand or supply if the price was set at £32?
(c) What would be the excess demand or supply if the price was set at £80?
(d) What is the equilibrium price and quantity?
(e) If income rises and demand, as a result, rises by 20 million units at each level, what will be the new equilibrium price?

Question 2

In the table below tick the appropriate column to show the impact of the change given on the market for cinema tickets.

Change Demand shift right Demand shift left Supply shift right Supply shift left
There is an increase in real incomes
Stelios Haji-Ioannou rolls out the EasyCinema low price model nationwide
The commission paid to film distributors by the cinemas falls
Planning law changes to restrict the development of out-of-town entertainment complexes
Pay-per-view cable, satellite and internet film services are developed and grow in popularity
Spiralling film production costs mean fewer new releases
Cinema operators develop new premium services


Markets and prices - self-test questions

question

1

Market changes

The diagram below shows the market for 3G mobile phones. Which of the following events might have caused the shift in the demand curve?

ds_d_right

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. The economies of scale would reduce costs and therefore shift the supply curve to the right.Yes, that's correct. An increase in advertising may shift the demand curve to the right.No, that's not right. An increase in interest rates will reduce disposable income and therefore shift the demand curve to the left.No, that's not right. This will have the effect of shifting the supply curve to the right.
Check your answer

2

Market changes

The diagram below shows the market for coffee. Which of the following events might have caused the shift in the supply curve?
ds_s_right

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This would increase the demand for coffee. No, that's not right. This would decrease the demand for coffee.No, that's not right. An increase in income would shift the demand curve to the right.Yes, that's correct. This would shift the supply curve for coffee to the right and encourage more production of coffee.
Check your answer

3

Market changes

The diagram below shows the market for olive oil. Which of the following events might have caused the shift in the supply curve?

ds_s_left

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This would shift the supply curve for olive oil to the right as there would be further supply of olives available. No, that's not right. This would shift the demand curve not the supply curve.No, that's not right. An increase in income would shift the demand curve to the right.Yes, that's correct. This would shift the supply curve for olive oil to the left as Spain is a major producer of olives and with a drought the harvest will be much lower.
Check your answer

4

Market changes

The diagram below shows the market for hard disk music players. Which of the following events might have caused the shift in the demand curve?

ds_d_left

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This would shift the supply curve for hard drive players to the right and not the demand curve. No, that's not right. This would shift the supply curve to the right as costs of production would be lower. The demand curve would not shift.No, that's not right. An increase in income would shift the demand curve to the right not to the left.Yes, that's correct. These new phones would be a substitute product and this would lead to a reduction in demand for hard drive players. This would shift the demand curve to the left.
Check your answer

5

Shifts in demand and supply curves

Consider the market for Mars Bars. Match the changes below with the shifts in supply and demand that they are likely to lead to.

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Well done. The supply curve will be affected by changes in costs and productivity, while the demand curve will be affected by health scares and changes in the price of substitutes.No, that's not quite right. Try again. The supply curve will be affected by changes in costs and productivity, while the demand curve will be affected by health scares and changes in the price of substitutes.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

6

Subsidy payments

Farmers are paid subsidies for the production of wheat. On a separate sheet of paper, draw a supply and demand diagram to show the impact of a subsidy and type an explanation of the diagram in the box below.

The impact of a subsidy is to shift the supply curve for the product to the right as shown in the diagram below. This is because the farmers become more willing to supply the good at each and every price. The supply curve shifts vertically downwards by the amount of the subsidy.

subsidy

Check your answer

7

Shifts in demand

Choose appropriate phrases from the drop down boxes below to complete the explanation of shifts of a demand curve and movements along demand curves.

When the price of a good changes there will a the demand curve. If the price increases, there will be a movement upwards and to the left on the demand curve and this is called a in demand or a in quantity demanded. If there is a decrease in price, then there will be a movement downwards to the right and this is called an in demand or an in quantity demanded. However, if one of the determinants other than price changes then the whole demand curve will shift, either to the right or to the left. For example, if income increases, then the demand curve will shift to the . If, however, the price of a substitute falls, then the demand curve will shift to the .

Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

Market equilibrium - numerical

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

Question 1

For a linear demand function of Qd = 155 - 5P, calculate the values of quantity demanded for prices from $1 to $20.

Question 2

For a linear supply function of Qs = -25 + 10P, calculate the values of quantity supplied for prices from $1 to $20.

Question 3

Plot the demand and supply diagram for the values for quantity demanded and supplied calculated in questions 1 and 2.

Question 4

Using simultaneous equations calculate the equilibrium price and output. Show your working.

Question 5

The demand function changes to Qd = 125 - 5P.

  1. Calculate the new values for quantity demanded for prices from $1-$20.
  2. Calculate the new equilibrium price and output using simultaneous equations
  3. Plot the new demand curve as D2 on the demand and supply diagram. Use the diagram to confirm your answers to part (b).

Question 6

The supply function now changes to Qs = -15 + 15P.

  1. Calculate the new values for quantity supplied for prices from $1-$20.
  2. Calculate the new equilibrium price and output using simultaneous equations
  3. Plot the new supply curve as S2 on the demand and supply diagram. Use the diagram to confirm your answers to part (b).

Question 7

Suggest two reasons for:

  1. The change in the demand function from Qd = 155 - 5P to Qd = 125 - 5P.
  2. The change in the supply function from Qs = -25 + 10P to Qs = -15 + 15P.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Demand and supply - data response

question

Interaction of demand and supply

Oil Prices

"Experts see no relief from high oil prices. Even OPEC's promise to pump more crude has failed to cool markets" reads a headline in The International Herald Tribune -The Global Edition of the New York Times (7 April 2011. Matthew Saltmarsh). The article goes on to report on the oil conference in Paris held the previous day. The Chief Executive of the French oil company, Total, Christophe de Margerie, stated that whilst he would be happy for oil prices to go down to $80 he could not see it happening: "Demand plus costs are increasing - tell me how you could see a reduction in oil prices," he said.

He went on to say that oil prices were being buoyed (kept high) by the concerns of the political stability in the Middle East and the worries about the future of nuclear power as a result of the effects of the earthquake and tsunami in Japan last month. "Short term, there's enough capacity available," he said. "But for the long term the best way we can avoid rising prices is investment in projects, non-conventional energy and reducing consumption in all countries."

Question 1

Define the terms:

  1. demand
  2. market

Question 2

With the aid of a suitable diagram, explain how increased demand for oil and increased costs of production lead to higher oil prices.

Question 3

Using your knowledge of economics and of the real world, explain how uncertainty in a market can lead to buyers stockpiling reserves of a good such as oil regardless of high prices.

Question 4

Evaluate the likely success of the imposition of policies by a government to promote non-conventional energy, such as bio-fuels, and reduction of oil consumption.

High Food Prices

question

"Rush to biofuels playing role in hunger and higher prices." (International Herald and Tribune. 7 April 2011. Elisabeth Rosenthal.) In her article Ms Rosenthal states:

"The starchy cassava plant has long been an ingredient in everything from tapioca pudding and ice cream to paper and animal feed.

"But last year, 98% of cassava chips exported from Thailand, the world's largest cassava exporter, went to just one place and for just one purpose: to China to make biofuel. Driven by new demand, Thai exports of cassava chips have increased nearly fourfold since 2008, and the price of cassava has roughly doubled." It can be seen that increased demand has led to an increase in price which has signalled to producers in Thailand to supply more cassava in the market.

She then goes on to write "Each year an ever larger portion of the world's crops, from cassava to corn to sugar to palm oil, is being diverted for biofuels as developed countries laws mandating greater use of non-fossil fuels and emerging powerhouses like China seek new sources of energy ....... But many experts are calling on countries to scale back their headlong rush in to green fuel development, arguing that ambitious biofuel targets and mediocre harvests of some crucial crops is contributing to high prices, hunger and political instability".

Question 1

Define the terms:

  1. supply
  2. market

Question 2

Using an appropriate diagram, show how increased demand from China and increased supply by Thailand of cassava has caused changes in price in the market for cassava chips.

Question 3

Explain how the diversion of traditional food products, such as cassava and palm oil, to biofuel production can lead to high food prices, hunger and possible political instability in a country such as Egypt.

Question 4

Using your knowledge of economics and of the real world, evaluate the decision by governments in developed countries to move to new sources of energy in the form of green fuel development.

Oil - the rise and rise

Read the article 2011 Halftime Report: Oil Outlook Remains Strong and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also want to read to help answer the questions:


question

Question 1

Define the following terms used in the text of the article 'Halftime Report':

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, explain the changes that have taken place in the oil market.

Question 3

Analyse the extent to which the rise in oil prices has been as a result of policies pursued by OPEC - the oil cartel.

Question 4

Analyse the extent to which the increase in oil prices will impact on countries in the developed world

Question 5

Discuss the likelihood of oil prices rising further.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Extension exercises:

Focusing on supply and demand factors over the next 2 to 3 years, write a 500 to 1000 word report on one of the following:

New Zealand dairy prices increase

Read the article Dairy product prices to rise despite milk freeze and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Identify the key determinants of demand for dairy products in New Zealand.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, explain the changes that have taken place in the market for dairy products.

Question 3

Analyse the likely impact of the increase in the price of milk on

  1. pizzas and
  2. soya milk and other milk substitutes.

Question 4

Discuss the extent to which manufacturers of dairy products will be able to pass on the increased costs to consumers in the form of higher prices.

Orange juice will soon be a luxury

Read the article Orange juice will soon be 'luxury' and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Using supply and demand diagrams as appropriate, explain the impact of the freezing weather in Florida and China on the world price of oranges.

Question 3

With the use of supporting diagrams, analyse the impact of non-price determinants on the supply of, and demand for, orange juice.

Question 4

To what extent are retailers able to absorb price increases from their suppliers, rather than pass them onto consumers?

The true face of global warming

Read the article Mozambique's riots: The true face of global warming and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Explain the impact of financial speculators on the prices of food commodities.

Question 3

Using supply and demand diagrams as appropriate, analyse the 'Deeper reasons for Mozambique's price hike'.

Question 4

'Global commodity speculators continue to treat food as if it were the same as television sets, with little end in sight to what the World Development Movement has called "gambling on hunger in financial markets". To what extent can international governments influence food prices to protect less developed countries, such as Mozambique?

How much is a 2p worth? Actually 3p

Read the article How much is a 2p worth? Actually 3p and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also like to read the article Mint warns against melting coins.


question

Question 1

Examine the factors that have caused the rise in copper prices on world markets.

Question 2

Describe the principal factors affecting the demand for copper and other metals.

Question 3

Explain what is meant by the terms "goldilocks economy" and "super-cycle"? (See the Guardian article.)

Labour mobility

Read the article EU free movement of labour map and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Explain the reasons why some EU countries have maintained restrictions on workers entering their countries.

Question 2

Analyse the advantages and disadvantages of increasing labour mobility in Europe.

Question 3

Using diagrams, as appropriate, evaluate the impact on greater labour mobility on the labour market of one of the 'Old EU' countries.

1.1 Competitive markets - simulations and activities

In this section are a series of simulations and activities on the topic - Markets. These simulations and activities might include:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to move on to the next page.

PlotIT - Build a demand curve

Consider the (imaginary) data in the following table. This shows the annual demand for tennis shoes in three sections of the market. Calculate the total (annual) market demand. Jot this down on a piece of paper. You may like to check your answer.

Price (£) Tennis club members ('000s) Players, but not club members ('000s) Non-tennis players ('000s) Total market ('000s)
100 6 1 0
80 7 3 0
60 8 6 2
40 9 10 8
20 10 18 20


From the table, plot each of the figures for total market demand on the following diagram. To do this, click your mouse on the graph axes for the position of each of the plots. When you have done this, the demand curve will automatically be drawn.

You may like to check your answer to see if it matches the correct curve.

question

1

Expansion/contraction of demand

If the price of tennis shoes falls, there will be an extension in demand.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. A fall in price leads to an extension in demand.No, that's not right. The statement is true. A fall in price leads to an extension in demand.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Demand for tennis shoes

A higher rate of economic growth will lead to an extension in demand.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. An increase in economic growth will lead to a shift in the demand curve. An extension in demand is a move along the demand curve.No, that's not right. The statement is false. An increase in economic growth will lead to a shift in the demand curve. An extension in demand is a move along the demand curve.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Step by step - a decrease in demand


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step by step - an increase in demand


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step by step - a decrease in supply


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step by step - an increase in supply


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

PlotIT - Build a demand and supply diagram

The demand and supply schedules for organically grown wheat are shown in the following table. From it we can see that at a price of £200, farmers will produce (or plan to plant and produce) 220 tonnes per annum (p.a.); likewise consumers will buy 220 tonnes p.a. at this price. However, the price of non-organic wheat falls dramatically and is considerably cheaper than organic wheat. As a result the demand for organically grown wheat changes by 80 tonnes at all prices. Calculate the new level of demand at each price level. Jot this down on a piece of paper. You may like to check your answer.

Price per tonne (£) 50 100 150 200 250 300 350
Tonnes supplied p.a. 100 140 180 220 260 300 340
Tonnes demanded p.a. 400 320 260 220 180 140 120
New tonnes demanded p.a


In the diagram below plot the original supply and demand curves and the new demand curve given this change in the price of non-organic wheat.

You may like to check your answer to see if it matches the correct demand and supply curves.

question

1

Market for organic wheat

What will be the shortage/surplus at the original price of £200 per tonne?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct (i.e. 220 tonnes supplied minus 140 tonnes demanded).No, that's not right. 220 tonnes will be supplied and 140 tonnes will be demanded. This gives a surplus of 80 tonnes, not a shortage.No, that's not right. 220 tonnes will be supplied and 140 tonnes will be demanded. This gives a surplus of 80 tonnes.No, that's not right. 220 tonnes will be supplied and 140 tonnes will be demanded. This gives a surplus of 80 tonnes.
Check your answer

2

Equilibrium

What will be the new equilibrium price and quantity?

The new equilibrium price will be £150 per tonne and the quantity demand and supplied will be 180 tonnes p.a. (where the supply curve and the new demand curve intersect).Check your answer

DragIT - Demand and supply

The following diagram shows the demand and supply of good X. For each of the following, click on either the demand or supply curve (or first one and then the other) and drag the curve(s) to a position that illustrates the question to help you match the events to the particular change.

question

1

Shifts in demand and supply

Match the following changes to the shifts that will take place.

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not right. Have another go. Try shifting the curve in the diagram to see the effect on price and quantity.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Diagram toolkit

In the diagram toolkit you get given a panel showing possible curves and labels and you then drag these curves onto targets on the diagram to try to build an appropriate diagram.

There are a number of sections. Follow the links below to access the different sections or use the table of contents on the left.

Why not try the one below as some practice? Drag curves and labels onto the targets on the diagram to build a demand and supply diagram showing a market in equilibrium. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Click on the right arrow to start trying out the diagram toolkit.

Air travel (1)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

Number 4

Click on the right arrow try some further examples.

Air travel (2)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

Click on the right arrow try some further examples.

Air travel (3)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

Click on the right arrow try some further examples.

iPods (1)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

Number 4

Click on the right arrow try some further examples.

iPods (2)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

Click on the right arrow try some further examples.

iPods (3)

On the diagrams below, drag curves and labels from the panel on the right to build the appropriate diagram. Once you think the diagram is right, click 'Check answer'. To see the correct answer, click the 'Feedback' button.

Number 1

Number 2

Number 3

1.2 Elasticities

In the previous sections we explained markets, the rules of supply and demand, market equilibrium, the price mechanism and market efficiency and how demand and supply are used to calculate market price and plot market equilibrium. In this section we explain the concept of elasticity.

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\core.gif.

By the end of this section you should be able to:

1.2 Elasticities - notes

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\elastic_ball.jpgThis unit, with its numbers, will scare some students. Be positive, the maths is easy; the key is to understand what the words mean. It is the language, rather than the numbers, that is usually the problem.

In the last unit we saw what demand is, and what its determinants are. We know that demand is sensitive to changes in these determinants; it is important to know how sensitive. Economists do this by measuring elasticity. In particular, they study price, income and cross price elasticity of demand. In addition they study price elasticity of supply. This is new language, so some definitions are needed.

Elasticity is simply the economist's word for responsiveness. For example, price elasticity shows how responsive demand is to changes in price. Economists will, in this case, be measuring how much the demand for a good or service will change as a result in a change in its price. In this section we consider the following topics in detail:

Price elasticity of demand (PED)

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Price elasticity of demand (PED)

A measure of the resposniveness of the demand for a product to changes in its own price.


PED - formula

Price elasticity of demand is calculated and defined as:

Where Qd = Quantity demanded
and P = Price

The % change in quantity demanded is divided by the % change in price.

Some students find it difficult to remember which way up this equation is. The following 'aide memoire' may be of use. You usually put your dinner (demand) on your plate (price). Demand is over price, D over P!

Price elasticity is negative because price and quantity demanded usually vary inversely with each other. This is so common that the sign is ignored. Do not forget, when price increases, demand falls and vice versa. If necessary, go back and review the section relating to the law of demand.

PED values


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Determinants of price elasticity


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Calculating PED

You will be expected to calculate and use elasticity, and to interpret given data. This may happen in any of the papers that are taken. As we have seen price elasticity of demand is calculated and defined as:

Where Qd = Quantity demanded
and P = Price

So, to calculate the value of the price elasticity, we simply need to substitute the appropriate values in this equation. Let's look at this calculation through some examples.

eg

Example 1 - price elasticity of demand

A product sells for $100 per unit, and the demand at that price is 10,000 units per week. The firm increases its price to $110 each and sales fall to 8,000 units per week. What is the price elasticity of demand for the product, and what effect will the price rise have on the firm's revenue?

P1 $100 Q1 10,000
P2 $110 Q2 8,000
Change in price +10 Change in quantity demanded -2,000
Percentage change in price +10% Percentage change in quantity demanded -20%


Price elasticity of demand = % change in quantity demand / % change in price = -20 / +10 = -2

Demand in this case is elastic, i.e. the numerical value is greater than 1.

Sales revenue was $100 x 10,000 = $1,000,000 and became $110 x 8,000 = $880,000

Revenue has fallen.

Remember, if demand for a good or service is price elastic then an increase in price will decrease both sales and sales revenue. However, a price cut will increase both sales and revenue.

eg

Example 2 - price elasticity of demand

A product has a PED (price elasticity of demand) of 0.8. At present it sells for $10 and sales have reached 100,000 per month. The firm is planning a price increase to $12 each. What can it expect to happen to sales and revenue if it goes ahead with the rise?

First remember that price elasticity is negative, and then use the formula that you know.

P1 = $10 P2 = $12 Change in P = $2 (+20%)


PED = 0.8

Cross-multiply and find:

% change in quantity = -0.8 x 20 = - 16%

New sales = 84% (100,000) = 84,000

Price would go up and sales would fall, as expected.

Revenue was $10 x 100,000 = $1,000,000

Would become $12 x 84,000 = 1,008,000

Revenue, on the other hand, would increase by $8,000.

Measuring elasticity

Price elasticity is based on the demand curve. In fact, the elasticity is the gradient of the demand curve at a particular point. i.e mathematicians will note that it is the differential of the demand function, in fact. This means it is a static measure, since it is based on static, or equilibrium data.

In the real world elasticity is very difficult to measure. There are far too many variables, and these change all the time. Quantitative data is rare, but qualitative data can be useful.

It is useful to remember that essentials tend to be price inelastic, as are addictive products. This is one of the reasons behind the taxing of alcohol and tobacco by many governments.

Elasticity along a straight line demand curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Elasticity and revenue

PED and business decisions - the effect of price changes on revenue

PED is important for business decision making as it determines the effect of price changes on total revenue. When a business is considering increasing or decreasing price, it is important to know the resulting impact on its sales revenue.

Remember that if demand for a good or service is price inelastic then an increase in price will decrease sales but increase sales revenue. However, a price cut will increase both sales but decrease sales revenue.

Firms like the demand for their product if possible to be inelastic. This means that any increase in price that they put in place will have proportionately less of an effect on demand and their total revenue will rise.

If price elasticity is 1, then revenue is the same all the time, even if prices are increased or decreased.

The changes in revenue for different elasticity values are summarised in the table below.

Price elasticity value Price change Impact on firm's revenue Explanation
Elastic Increase Fall Elastic demand will mean that when price increases, demand will fall by a greater percentage than the price increased. This means a fall in revenue.
Elastic Decrease Increase Elastic demand will mean that when price falls, demand will increase by a greater percentage than the price decreased. This means an increase in revenue.
Inelastic Increase Increase Inelastic demand will mean that when price increases, demand will fall by a smaller percentage than the price increased. This means an increase in revenue.
Inelastic Decrease Fall Inelastic demand will mean that when price falls, demand will increase by a smaller percentage than the price decreased. This means a fall in revenue.


Consider the following demand curves:

Unit elastic demand

d_unitel_revchange_f

Figure 1 Unit elasticity of demand

Here the curve is a rectangular hyperbola. Thus all rectangles under the curve are equal in area and each rectangle equals total revenue (for example, the blue and red rectangles are equal). Thus, total revenue remains unchanged as price changes.

In this case it might not be worthwhile for a business to lower price as the extra demand would not bring forth any extra revenue (MR = 0), but it is highly likely that extra costs would be incurred in producing the additional output.

Elastic demand

d_el_revchange_f

Figure 2 Elastic demand (PED greater than 1 but less than infinity)

Here a decision to reduce price would lead to an increase in total revenue. As price falls from OP1 to OP2, there is a more than proportionate rise in the quantity demanded from OQ1 to OQ2 and total revenue rises from OP1 x OQ1 to OP2 x OQ2. The fall in revenue from the lower price (the red area) is more than compensated by the rise in revenue from the extra sales (the blue area). The decision to lower price may well be sound in this case as total revenue will rise which may lead to higher profits, depending on the relationship between costs and revenue.

Conversely, a decision to raise price would lead to a fall in total revenue. A rise in price from OP2 to OP1 would cause a more than proportionate fall in demand and so reduce total revenue.

Where demand is elastic:

as price increases, total revenue falls

as price decreases, total revenue rises

Inelastic demand

d_inel_revchange_f

Figure 3 Inelastic demand (PED greater than 0, but less than one)

Here a decision to lower price would lead to a decrease in sales revenue. As price decreases from OP1 to OP2, there is a less than proportionate increase in demand from OQ1 to OQ2 and total revenue falls. We can see from figure 3 that the loss in revenue from the lower price (the red area) is less than the gain in revenue from the higher sales (the blue area) and so total revenue will fall.

Conversely, a decision to raise price from OP2 to OP1 would lead to a less than proportionate fall in demand from OQ2 to OQ1 and sales revenue would rise.

Where demand is inelastic:

as price increases, total revenue increases

as price decreases, total revenue decreases

Thus knowledge of the PED facing a firm's product or service enables rational pricing decisions to be made.

PED - primary vs manufactured

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\wheat.jpgIf we look at the PED values for primary commodities and manufactured goods, we can see straight away that generally primary commodities have relatively low PED values (inelastic), while manufactured goods will tend to have higher values (more elastic).

So why is this? Well, if we look back at the determinants of the PED value that we looked at previously, we can start to identify why this might be the case. Let's remind ourselves first of the determinants of the PED value:

In the table below is a comparison of two products - wheat (a primary commodity) and laptops (a manufactured good) - against each of these determinants.

Determinants Wheat Laptop
Availability of close substitutes Relatively few substitutes - effectively a necessity Reasonable number of substitutes depending on precise task (e.g. games consoles etc.)
Luxury or necessity? Necessity Luxury
Proportion of income spent Depends on nature of economy, but generally relatively low Depends on nature of economy, but generally relatively high - a one-off purchase
Addictive N/A N/A
Time period Used over a short period - consumed immediately Used over a long period
Number of uses Single use - food Multiple uses


This helps us see why primary commodities will generally have a lower elasticity value than manufactured goods which will tend to be higher value luxuries rather than necessities and therefore more elastic.

PED and taxation

The imposition of a tax will mean that the price goes up (as supply shifts to the left). However, the amount of the price increase will depend on the elasticity of demand. Compare Figures 1 and 2 to see the difference.

tax_d_el

Figure 1 Tax imposed on a good with elastic demand

tax_d_inel

Figure 2 Tax imposed on a good with inelastic demand

question

1

Tax revenue

If you aimed as a government solely to reduce the consumption of the good, which type of good would you be taxing?

a)
b)
Yes - if the sole intention was to reduce demand then this would be most effective if the good is elastic in demand. The tax would increase the price and reduce demand by proportionately more.No - if the sole intention was to reduce demand of the good then this will be less effective if the good was inelastic in demand. However, if the good has damaging external costs, then the government may nevertheless want to tax the good.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Tax revenue (2)

If you aimed as a government to tax goods simply to raise tax revenue, which type of good would you tax?

a)
b)
Yes - if demand is inelastic, then firms are able to increase the price without demand falling very much. This will mean that the revenue raised will be relatively greater than for a good with elastic demand.No, that's not right. If the demand is elastic, then little revenue will be raised. The tax will put the price up, but this will lead to a proportionately greater decrease in demand and the revenue raised from the tax will be lower.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

So, for a government wishing to raise revenue from indirect taxation, they will always tend to impose the taxes on goods with relatively inelastic demand. The more inelastic the demand, the more the price will rise and therefore the more of the tax will be passed on to the consumer.

Cross elasticity of demand

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Cross elasticity of demand (CED)

The cross elasticity is a measure of the responsiveness of the demand for one product to changes in the price of another product.


Cross elasticity - formula

Cross elasticity is calculated and defined as:

Where Qdx = Quantity demanded of Good X
and Py = Price of Good Y

The XED is calculated by dividing the % change in the quantity demanded for one good or service by the % change in the price of another. It must be noted, however, that the two goods/services must be connected in some way (see the discussion of complements and substitutes below).

Cross price elasticity varies from 0 to infinity. As before, the now familiar descriptions are used:

Value Description
0 Perfectly inelastic
Under 1 Inelastic
1 Unitary
Over 1 Elastic
Infinity Perfectly elastic


Significance of XED sign

The sign is as important as the numerical value, however.

Some products tend to be bought together, others are purchased in competition to each other. Products bought together are called complementary goods. Products which are in competition with each other are called substitute goods.

eg

Examples of complements are steak and chips, rice and curry, cars and petrol, torches and batteries, gas and gas cookers. Complementary goods have negative cross price elasticities. Perfect complements will have a cross price elasticity of - infinity: negative infinity

Example - complements

eg

Examples of substitutes are beef and lamb, gas and heating oil, petrol and diesel fuel. (Note that the substitution may not be possible at once, it may occur over time). Substitutes have positive cross price elasticities.

Example - substitutes

Cross price elasticity can change with time, therefore.

eg

Again, here are some examples of calculations.

Example 1 - cross price elasticity

Example 2 - cross price elasticity

XED and business decisions

Cross elasticity of demand: relevance for firms

Cross elasticity of demand (CED) is the responsiveness of demand for one good (good X) to a change in the price of another (good Y). Can you write down the FORMULA? Follow the link to check your answer.

The numerical value of the XED will depend on the relationship between the goods in question. If the goods are substitutes or complements, the numerical value of the XED will be much larger than if the two goods bear little relation to each other; i.e. a change in the price of one good will have a significant impact on the demand for the other good. This will be important for business decision making.

For example, consider two manufacturers of different brands of cola, for example (Coke and Pepsi). Let's call them Brand X and Brand Y, which are close substitutes for each other. The decision by the manufacturer of Brand X to lower price will, other things being equal, lead to an increase in the consumption of Brand X cola. If the manufacturer of Brand Y cola leaves the price unchanged, he/she is likely to experience a decrease in demand as Brand X will become relatively, and possibly absolutely, more expensive than Brand Y. The manufacturer of Brand X is faced with an important pricing decision in order to compete effectively with the rival. Can you think of any other goods or services where such close substitutes can be found?

Conversely, consider the case of two goods that are complements, strawberries and cream. A very British example, but very true! A good harvest will increase the supply of strawberries (the supply curve will shift to the right) and lower their price. As a result, there will be a movement along the demand curve for strawberries, an extension of demand. Given that people like to pour cream on their strawberries to give extra taste, manufacturers of cream will have to make important output decisions if they are to meet the potential increase in demand for cream arising from higher consumption of strawberries. Cows cannot suddenly increase their supply of milk so producers may have to switch production from other dairy products to that of cream or choose to keep cream output at the same level forcing the price of cream to rise in the market.

Income elasticity of demand

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Income elasticity of demand (YED)

The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to changes in real income.

YED - formula

Income elasticity of demand is calculated and defined as:

Where Y = real income
and Qd is the quantity demanded

YED is calculated by dividing the %change in the quantity demanded for a good or service by the % change in income.

Normal and inferior goods

Elasticity can be calculated and a range of values found. What do they show? What do they tell an economist?

Income elasticity may be positive or negative. If income elasticity is negative, demand falls as real income rises. Goods or services with such elasticity are called inferior goods. These might include supermarket own brands or fake leather compared to real leather, for example. Write down some other examples of inferior goods.

If the income elasticity is positive, demand increases with real income. These goods are known as normal goods. If your income increases you might choose to buy more clothes or go to the cinema more often, for example. Write down some other examples of normal goods.

The sign reveals whether the good is inferior or normal.

Elasticity is given different names over different numerical ranges. Learn these, and the related diagrams.

eg

Some examples of calculations:

Example 1 - income elasticity of demand

Example 2 - income elasticity of demand

YED and business decisions

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\cd.jpgSignificance of YED for sectoral change (primary - secondary - tertiary) as economy grows

Economic growth is the increase in productive capacity of the economy and is best measured by the increase in real GDP (output) over a period of time. (Remember that the term real takes into account levels of inflation in an economy).

Typically, as economic growth occurs and real incomes and living standards rise over time, the primary sector tends to become relatively less important, while the secondary and tertiary sectors tend to become relatively more important. Fundamentally, this is because of the importance if YED.

In general, the products of the primary sector e.g. fruit, vegetables, rice, tend to have a low YED i.e. as real incomes rise, there tends to be a less than proportionate rise in demand for these products. No matter how rich you are, there is a limit to how much fruit and vegetables you can eat, so an increase in income may not stimulate a large increase in consumption of these goods. Consequently, the primary agricultural sector is likely to grow only slowly as living standards rise.

However, this would not be true for oil and other extracted minerals such as copper, iron and, also, diamonds and other precious and semi-precious stones, for example. Economies rich in primary resources will find that such products would have a relatively higher YED than basic agricultural products. Minerals, oil and gas, and gems for example, will have a derived demand inasmuch as they will be demanded for their use in the manufacturing sector. A study of a country such as Qatar in the Middle East will demonstrate how the primary sector plays a key and highly lucrative role in its GDP.

The demand for manufactured goods and the services of the tertiary sector, however, tend to have a very high YED. As we become better off, there tends to be a more than proportionate increase in demand for electrical equipment, furniture, banking, travel and tourism etc. Hence the secondary and tertiary sectors grow much more rapidly than the primary sector as living standards rise.

In the more developed countries, the tendency is for the tertiary sector to grow the most rapidly in response to rising real incomes. This is not because people in rich countries fail to buy more manufactured goods as they become better off. Rather, it is often the case that these goods are imported from other countries, often newly industrialised countries, which may be able to produce the manufactured goods with a comparative advantage, i.e. relatively more cheaply.

Thus YED has an important effect on resource allocation within an economy and the speed and nature of sectoral change as countries develop.

Price elasticity of supply

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Price elasticity of supply (PES)

The responsiveness of the quantity of a good supplied to changes in its price.

PES - formula

The value for price elasticity of supply is calculated and defined as:

PES is the % change in quantity supplied of a good or service divided by the % change in its price.

Possible PES values


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

PES - calculation

eg

Follow the links below to see some sample calculations if you are not sure about how to calculate the value of price elasticity of supply.

Example 1 - price elasticity of supply

Example 2 - price elasticity of supply

Price elasticity of supply measures the ability of a firm to increase or decrease its output in response to a change in price. This sensitivity changes with time, or rather with economic time and the degree of substitutability between factors of production.

Unitary elasticity of supply

Any straight-line supply function that passes through the origin has a coefficient of 1. Look at Figure 1. All the supply functions have an elasticity of 1.

s_elas_1

Figure 1 Supply schedules with unitary elasticity

Determinants of PES


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

PES - primary vs manufactured

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\wheat.jpgIf we look at the PES values for primary commodities and manufactured goods, we can see straight away that generally primary commodities have relatively low PES values (inelastic), while manufactured goods will tend to have higher values (more elastic).

So why is this? Well, if we look back at the determinants of the PES value that we looked at previously, we can start to identify why this might be the case. Let's remind ourselves first of the determinants of the PES value:

In the table below is a comparison of two products - wheat (a primary commodity) and laptops (a manufactured good) - against each of these determinants.

Determinants Wheat Laptop
The time period Relatively little opportunity to change supply - once planted, supply is effectively determined for a year Supply is quite flexible - increased globalisation means increased production capacity can be brought on relatively quickly
Substitutability Very difficult to substitute factors of production Factors of production relatively easy to substitute
Capacity factors Once fields have been planted for a season, capacity is effectively fixed. Only in the long-run can it be changed significantly. New capacity can be brought in relatively easily - particularly ina ore global economy
Stocks Relatively perishable and so difficult to hold stocks for any significant period of time Stocks can be held, though these may date as specifications improve


This helps us see why primary commodities will generally have a lower elasticity value than manufactured goods where production tends to be more flexible and therefore more elastic.

Summary

Having completed this session you should know and understand that:

1. The responsiveness of supply to changes in price is known as supply elasticity.
2. Elasticity of supply is normally positive.
3. Supply is perfectly inelastic if its coefficient is 0, inelastic if it is between 0 and 1, unitary if it is exactly 1, elastic if it is between 1 and infinity and perfectly elastic if it is infinity.
4. Price elasticity of supply of a product varies with time, economic time (i.e. very short run, short run, long run, very long run). It also depends on the substitutability of the factors of production used in its manufacture.

Section 1.2 Elasticities - questions

In this section are a series of questions on the topic - elasticities. The questions may include various types of questions. For example:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to work through the questions.

PED - short-answer

question

Question 1

'The demand for luxury cars is elastic, but the coefficient for Jaguar cars is higher than that for the luxury part of the car market as a whole'.

Why is this the case?

Question 2

'The price elasticity of demand for commuter rail travel is inelastic but that for vacation rail travel is elastic'. Comment on this fact.

Question 3

An exclusive pen manufacturer sells 4,000 pens per month at a price of £40 each. When the price is reduced to £30 sales increase to 6,000 pens per month.

(a) Calculate the price elasticity of demand for the pens over this price range.
(b) Is demand elastic, unit elastic or inelastic?
(c) Calculate the change in revenue due to the change in price.

Question 4

The table below shows the demand schedule for a good. Complete the following table, using the appropriate equation, with the total expenditure and indicate in the elasticity column whether the good is elastic or inelastic over that price range.

Price (£) Demand (per week) Total expenditure Elasticity - elastic / inelastic?
1 50 ****
2 40
3 30
4 25
5 20
6 16
7 13
8 10
9 8
10 5


Price, income and cross elasticity - self-test questions

question

1

Price elasticity

A cut in price from $1.50 to $1.20 sees demand for a product rise by 10%. What would the price elasticity of demand be for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, have you got the formula upside down?No, this would mean the percentage changes were the same and they're not!Yes, well done.No. Have you calculated the correct percentage change in price?
Check your answer

2

Price elasticity

A firm increases its price from $8 to $12 and sees demand for the product fall by 20%. What would the price elasticity of demand be for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, well done.No, this would mean the percentage changes were the same and they're not!No, have you got the formula upside down?No. Have you calculated the correct percentage change in price?
Check your answer

3

Income elasticity

What type of good would you expected to have a negative income elasticity of demand?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, this type of good would have a positive income elasticity because the demand for them rises as income rises.Yes, the demand for these goods falls as incomes rise and so the income elasticity is negative.No, these normally have a strong positive income elasticity.No, this is a good where demand rises as the price rises. It is therefore related to price and not income.
Check your answer

4

Income elasticity

If disposable incomes rise by 5% and the income elasticity of demand is known to be 0.5, what change in demand would we expect to see?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, this would only be the case if the income elasticity was 2. If income elasticity is positive, then, if income increases, there will always be an increase in demand.No, this would only be the case if the income elasticity was 1. If income elasticity is positive, then, if income increases, there will always be an increase in demand.No, this would only occur if the income elasticity was negative. If income elasticity is positive, then, if income increases, there will always be an increase in demand.Yes, well done. If income elasticity is positive, then, if income increases, there will always be an increase in demand.
Check your answer

5

Price elasticity

If a price cut does not lead to an increase in revenue, we might infer that the demand for this product is?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, well done. If a good is price inelastic, then a cut in price will lead to a smaller proportionate change in demand. This will mean that revenue earned from the good will fall.No, this refers to the effect of changes in income. You need to look at the price elasticity.No, a price cut would boost revenue if it were price elastic.No, this refers to the effect of changes in income. You need to look at the price elasticity.
Check your answer

6

Price elasticity

If the price elasticity of demand for a product is known to be (-) 2.5 and the firm cuts the price of this product by 5%, what change would we expect to see in the demand for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, have you got the formula upside down?Yes, well done. From the price elasticity we know that the change in demand will be two and a half times the change in price. A cut in price will lead to an increase in demand and the increase will therefore be 12.5%.No, have you used the formula correctly?No, have you put the correct data into the formula?
Check your answer

7

Price elasticity

If the price elasticity of demand for a product is known to be (-) 0.5 and the firm increases the price of this product by 10%, what change would we expect to see in the demand for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, have you got the formula upside down?No, have you taken into account the minus sign?No, have you used the formula correctly?Yes, well done. From the price elasticity we know that the change in demand will be half the change in price. An increase in price will lead to an decrease in demand and the decrease will therefore be 5%.
Check your answer

8

Price elasticity

If the price elasticity of demand for a product is known to be (-) 2.5 and the firm increases the price of this product by 5%, what change would we expect to see in the demand for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, have you used the formula correctly?No, have you taken into account the minus sign?No, have you got the formula upside down?Yes, well done. From the price elasticity we know that the change in demand will be two and a half times the change in price. An increase in price will lead to an decrease in demand and the decrease will therefore be 12.5%.
Check your answer

9

Sales in a recession

In a recession, which sort of good would we expect to see a rise in sales for?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, not at all!No, why would we need more of a necessity in a recession?Yes, well done. Inferior goods are ones where demand falls as income rises. As income falls in a recession, we would therefore expect to see a rise in sales.No, normal goods are ones where demand rises as income rises. As income falls in a recession, we would therefore expect to see a fall in sales.
Check your answer

10

Price elasticity

A cut in price from $75 to $60 sees demand for a product rise by from 1,200 units to 1,500 units. What would the price elasticity of demand be for this product?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, have you got the formula upside down?No, this would mean the percentage changes were the same - and they're not!Yes, well done. Price has fallen by 20% and demand has risen by 25%. If we divide the change in demand by the change in price we get 1.25.No. Have you calculated the correct percentage change in price?
Check your answer

11

Income elasticity

If disposable incomes rise by 2% and the income elasticity of demand is known to be 1.5, what change in demand would we expected to see?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, well done. We know from the income elasticity that the change in demand will be one and a half times the change in income. As income has increased by 2%, demand will therefore increase by 3%.No, have you used the formula correctly?No, have you used the formula correctly?No, this would only occur if the income elasticity was negative. The number is right but the sign is wrong.
Check your answer

12

Price elasticity

The image below shows a medium size yacht. What would you expect the value of the price elasticity of demand for yachts to be?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, well done. Yachts would generally be considered a luxury good and because of the high proportion of income being spent on them, we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively elastic.No, unit elasticity means that demand and price change by the same amount. This is unlikely to be the case for yachts.No, we would generally expect the demand for necessities to be price inelastic. Yachts would generally be considered a luxury good and because of the high proportion of income being spent on them, we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively elastic.No, zero price elasticity means that there is no change in demand as price changes and this is very unlikely for yachts as they are generally considered a luxury.
Check your answer

13

Price elasticity

The image below shows cigarettes. What would you expect the value of the price elasticity of demand for cigarettes to be?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Cigarettes are addictive and so people tend to be less responsive to changes in price. This means that we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively inelastic.No, unit elasticity means that demand and price change by the same amount. This is unlikely to be the case for cigarettes.Yes, that's correct. Cigarettes are addictive and so people tend to be less responsive to changes in price. This means that we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively inelastic.No, zero price elasticity means that there is no change in demand as price changes and this is very unlikely for cigarettes as they are generally considered addictive.
Check your answer

14

Price elasticity

The image below shows wheat being harvested. What would you expect the value of the price elasticity of demand for wheat to be?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Wheat is a necessity (as a raw material for bread and so on) and so people tend to be less responsive to changes in price. This means that we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively inelastic.No, unit elasticity means that demand and price change by the same amount. This is unlikely to be the case for wheat.Yes, that's correct. Wheat is a necessity (as a raw material for bread and so on) and so people tend to be less responsive to changes in price. This means that we would expect the price elasticity to be relatively inelastic.No, zero price elasticity means that there is no change in demand as price changes and this is very unlikely for wheat as it is generally considered a necessity.
Check your answer

PES - short answer

question

Question 1

How would you expect the price elasticity of supply for houses to change over time? Explain your answer. (5 marks)

Question 2

Rank the following products according to the value of their price elasticity of supply, starting with the most elastic. Give reasons for your answers.

(a) Computers
(b) Houses
(c) Strawberries
(d) Olives
(e) Ice cream

Inflation soars for staple foods

Read the article Inflation Tough to Digest for Asia as Food Costs Soar From Pork to Onions and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Explain how the factors affecting demand are likely to differ between developed and developing countries.

Question 2

Explain possible values for the price elasticity of demand for staple goods, such as rice, in (a) developed countries and (b) developing countries.

Question 3

Using appropriate diagrams, examine the principal factors that have led to the rapid rise in the price of staple products on world markets.

Question 4

Evaluate the likely success of the Indian government's decision to buy onions from abroad, and to impose an export ban, as a method of reducing the price of onions.

find_out

Investigate! Develop an inquiring mind

Global food prices remain high, partly due to increasing fuel prices, and the World Bank's Food Price Index is around its 2008 peak. Since June 2010, an additional 44 million people fell below the $1.25 poverty line as a result of higher food prices. Simulations show that a further 10% increase in the Food Price Index could lead to 10 million people falling into poverty, and a 30% increase could increase poverty by 34 million people. Low-income and lower-middle-income countries are experiencing on average 5% points higher food price inflation compared to better-off countries.

World Bank report 2011

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Produce a 500 - 1000 word article for publication in a national magazine, outlining the reasons for global increases in food prices, their effects and possible actions to support those countries and communities most affected.

You may wish to read these additional articles and watch the YouTube video to provide more background:

World Bank Food Price Watch

Food Costs Rising as Coke, Chipotle Pass on Commodity Gains

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

World Bank: Challenging the Food Crisis


Elastic iPods

Read the article In time of need, Apple's new icon, a nation turns its lonely eyes to you and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Define the term income elasticity of demand.

Question 2

Examine the likely value of the income elasticity of demand for iPods.

Question 3

Analyse

  1. two goods (other than iPods) that are likely to face an increase in demand and
  2. two goods that are likely to face a decrease in demand as a result of the US fiscal stimulus.

DaVinci scandal exposes tacky Chinese nouveau tastes

Read the article DaVinci scandal exposes tacky Chinese nouveau tastes and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

With the use of an appropriate diagrams compare and contrast Veblen and Giffen goods.

Question 2

Using examples, discuss the extent to which Veblen and Giffen goods exist in real life.

Keep on boating

Read the article Fuel prices not expected to impact boating participation this summer and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Define the term 'cross price elasticity of demand'.

Question 2

Identify the principal determinants of the demand for powerboats.

Question 3

Analyse the main factors that determine the cross price elasticity of demand for powerboats with respect to the price of fuel.

Question 4

Discuss the likely difference between the values of the cross price elasticity of demand for cars with respect to the price of fuel and the cross price elasticity of demand for powerboats with respect to fuel.

Coffee prices remain high

Read the article Coffee prices to remain high and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Identify the main factors that have led to the increase in coffee prices.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, illustrate the likely impact of the rise in the price of coffee beans on the market for instant coffee.

Question 3

Comment on the likely value of the price elasticity of demand for instant coffee.

Question 4

Discuss the extent to which coffee producers will be able to pass on the increase in the price of coffee beans to consumers.

SUV's - cross elastic?

Read the article High cost of fuel drives people into smaller cars and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

You may also like to read the following article to support your answer:


question

Question 1

Describe the main factors that led to a fall in demand for SUVs.

Question 2

Explain the following statement: Petrol and SUV's are complements. SUV's and Hybrids are substitutes.

Question 3

What strategies could the car manufacturers adopt to try to reduce the cross elasticity of demand for SUVs with respect to the fuel price?

Question 4

Explain the external costs that arise from sales of SUVs.

Oil Prices

question

Oil prices are frequently described as being volatile. They are subject to large variations in prices over time. In the first three months of 2011, Brent crude oil was quoted in the news as being up 28%.

Question 1

What factors are likely to affect the price of crude oil?

Question 3

Draw demand and supply diagrams to show the effect of:

  1. Rising US demand for oil
  2. OPEC relaxing quotas on oil to try to prevent the oil price rising further
  3. Civil unrest in Libya, Bahrain and Syria

Question 4

What would you expect the value of the price elasticity of demand for oil to be? Explain your answer.

Question 5

Analyse the impact that the higher oil price is likely to have on:

  1. Individual national economies
  2. The global economy

Scare tactics lift prices for smokers

Read the article Scare tactics lift prices for smokers and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\nb.gif

N.B. the Financial Times online requires registration to access their articles. This is free and allows access to up to 10 articles every 30 days. The following screen will appear when you click on the above link:

Once registered and signed in, the link will go the appropriate article.

The FT is an excellent economics resource and free registration would be beneficial for your studies. E-mail alerts are also possible with registration, which will provide you with instant headlines and information.


question

Question 1

Given that consumption will likely continue to decline in the mid-single digit range, pricing is necessary to drive top-line growth. Using information from the article, explain this statement.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, illustrate the changes that have taken place in the market for cigarettes.

Question 3

Assess the effectiveness of indirect taxation as a tool to improve public health by reducing smoking.

Question 4

Discuss the factors that may lead to a notable shift in demand "elasticity".

Section 1.2 Elasticities - simulations and activities

In this section are a series of simulations and activities on the topic - elasticities. These simulations and activities might include:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to move on to the next page.

DragIT - Calculating elasticity

In the diagram below, shift the demand curve to the right by 15 units. Do this by clicking on the 'D1' label and, keeping the mouse pressed, drag it to the right. Note that the slope remains the same (i.e. -5). Once you have done this, try the questions below.

question

1

Price elasticity

What is the value of the price elasticity on demand curve D1 when the price rises from £5 to £7?

The price has risen from £5 to £7 - this is a 40% change in price. When the price rises, the quantity demanded falls from 25 to 15. This is a 40% change in quantity. The percentage change in demand divided by the percentage change in price (40%/40%) is therefore 1.Check your answer

2

Price elasticity

What is the value of the price elasticity on demand curve D2 (once dragged to its new position) when the price rises from £5 to £7?

The price has risen from £5 to £7 - this is a 40% change in price. When the price rises, the quantity demanded falls from 40 to 30. This is a 25% change in quantity. The percentage change in demand divided by the percentage change in price (25%/40%) is therefore 0.625.Check your answer

DragIT - Elasticity

question

In this section you can check that you know all the elasticity formulae. In the exercises below, you need to drag the blue buttons on the right onto the orange target areas to build the relevant elasticity formula. Have a go at each in turn. Try to get them right straight away, rather than by trial and error!

Price elasticity of supply

Price elasticity of demand

N.B. A way of remembering this formula is to think of 'dinner (D) on your plate (P)'. In other words demand divided by price.

Income elasticity of demand

Cross elasticity of demand

Price elasticity of demand for exports

Income elasticity of demand for exports

1.3 Government intervention

In the previous sections we explained markets, the rules of supply and demand, market equilibrium, the price mechanism and market efficiency and how demand and supply are used to calculate market price and plot market equilibrium. We then explained the concepts of elasticity. In this section, we consider the role and effects of government intervention in the economy.

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\core.gif

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

1.3 Government Intervention - notes

Introduction

We looked briefly under supply at the impact of a tax and you should be clear now that a tax will shift the supply curve to the left. In fact, it shifts the supply curve vertically upwards by the amount of the tax.

However, we need to look at this in a little more detail as there are different types of taxes:


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Specific (or per unit) tax

A specific tax is a fixed amount of tax charged on each unit. A specific tax will shift the supply curve vertically upwards by the amount of the tax. Examples include cigarette, petrol and alcohol taxes.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Ad-valorem tax

A tax that is levied (charged) as a percentage of the selling price. An example of an ad valorem tax would be VAT (Value Added Tax, a sales tax).

The impact of taxation

Ad-valorem and specific taxes will have different effects on the supply curve. First the specific tax. We know that this is a fixed amount which is why Chancellors / Treasury Ministers tend to increase these each year - if they did not they would be losing out. Since it is a fixed amount whatever the price of the good, it will shift the supply curve parallel upwards as shown in Figure 1.

tax

Figure 1 Specific (or unit) tax

However, the ad-valorem tax is a percentage of the selling price. This means that at low prices the tax will be relatively little (10% of $1 is just 10c), but at higher prices the tax levied will be higher (10% of $10 is $1). This means that the supply curve shifts to the left and outwards as price increases. This is shown in Figure 2.

tax_av

Figure 2 Ad-valorem tax

Tax revenue


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Tax incidence

hl_go

Compare and contrast the two interactions below to see the difference in imposing a tax on a good with inelastic demand and one with elastic demand.


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:



If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

hl_start

Calculating effects of a specific tax

hl_startS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to understand how to calculate the impact of indirect taxes on the market equilibrium from demand and supply functions. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Indirect taxes

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating impact of a tax - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 120 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -30 + 10P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $3 - $15.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.
  3. Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.
  4. If the government imposes a specific tax per unit of $3, plot the new supply curve on the original supply and demand diagram.
  5. Use the diagram to find out the new equilibrium price and quantity.
  6. Calculate the tax revenue received by the government.
  7. Calculate the revenue received by the firms:
    1. before the tax
    2. after the tax
  8. Calculate consumer expenditure:
    1. before the tax
    2. after the tax

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

The impact of subsidies


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Calculating effects of a subsidy

hl_go

For higher level, you need to be able to understand how to calculate the impact of subsidies on the market equilibrium from demand and supply functions. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Subsidies

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating effect of a subsidy - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 120 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -30 + 10P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $3 - $15.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.
  3. Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.
  4. If the government gives a subsidy per unit of $3, plot the new supply curve on the original supply and demand diagram.
  5. Use the diagram to find out the new equilibrium price and quantity.
  6. Calculate the amount spent by the government on the subsidy.
  7. Calculate the revenue received by the firms:
    1. before the subsidy
    2. after the subsidy
  8. Calculate consumer expenditure:
    1. before the subsidy
    2. after the subsidy

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Price controls

pricePrice controls are controls that governments (or other authorities) put in place to try to influence the outcome of a market. For example, a government may feel that a price is too high and so set a maximum price for the good or service. An example of this may be rent controls - limits on the maximum rent that a landlord can charge for the use of a property.

Alternatively, a government may feel that the market results in a price that is too low and set a minimum price. An example of this occurs with labour markets where equilibrium wages can be very low and governments set a minimum wage. We look at this case in the section - minimum prices.

Markets can also be very unstable and this may persuade governments to try to intervene to stabilise the markets. This is particularly true with agricultural markets and we look at this situation in the section - intervention in agricultural markets.

Price ceilings


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Calculate effects of price ceiling

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to use a price ceiling diagram to be able to calculate changes in consumer expenditure. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Price ceiling

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating effect of a price ceiling - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 85 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -20 + 10P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $1 - $15.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.
  3. Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.
  4. The government then imposes a price ceiling of $4 on the market. Show this on the diagram.
  5. Calculate the excess demand as a result of this price ceiling.
  6. Calculate the level of consumer expenditure:
    1. before the price ceiling was imposed
    2. after the price ceiling was imposed

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Price floors


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Minimum wage

Many countries have now set a minimum wage. A minimum wage was first enacted in New Zealand in 1894 and there is now legislation setting minimum wages in more than 90% of all countries. The effect of a minimum wage will be very similar to that of a minimum price.

Assuming that the minimum wage is above the equilibrium level, wages will rise to the minimum wage level, but the number of employees will fall (to Qd in Figure 2), at least in the short run.

min_wage

Figure 2 Impact of a minimum wage

However, the extent of the unemployment will depend on the elasticity of demand for and elasticity of supply of labour. If both are very inelastic then there may be very little unemployment. Don't worry, this will be more fully explained later!

If the substitutability of labour is very low (in other words employers cannot substitute capital (machines) for labour), then this should help minimise the impact on unemployment.

However, unscrupulous employers may well employ workers illegally and pay less than the minimum wage. An informal market is again created. This is often found where countries have a large number of illegal immigrants.

question

Task

Use the web to find out if there is a minimum wage in your country. If there is, try to answer the following questions.

  1. What is the level of the minimum wage?
  2. What age does it start at?
  3. Are there any exceptions where employers are allowed to pay below the minimum wage?
  4. How much has it increased in real terms (compared to inflation) in the last five years?

Calculate effects of price floor

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

For higher level, you need to be able to use a price floor diagram to be able to calculate changes in consumer expenditure, firm's revenue and the cost to the government of buying any surplus. The presentation below goes through this. Click on the screenshot or link below to open the presentation. It will open in a new web window. You will need a headset or speakers to listen to the explanation.

Price floor

hl_stop

Calculating effect of a price ceiling - example

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\eg.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 95 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -40 + 10P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions. Once you have had a go at the questions, follow the link below to compare your answers.

  1. Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $1 - $15.
  2. Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.
  3. Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.
  4. The government then imposes a price floor of $4 on the market. Show this on the diagram.
  5. Calculate the excess supply as a result of this price floor.
  6. Calculate the level of consumer expenditure:
    1. before the price floor was imposed
    2. after the price floor was imposed
  7. Calculate how much the government would have to spend to purchase the excess supply as a result of the price floor.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Intervention in agricultural markets

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\wheat.jpgOne area where national governments and the EU intervene extensively is in agricultural markets. The aim of this intervention is normally to guarantee farmers a stable and secure income as agricultural markets can fluctuate significantly. One of the largest intervention schemes is the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) run by the European Union (EU).

Commodity agreements

These may take the form of attempts to stabilise prices, through the operation of a buffer stock scheme or attempts to raise prices by forming a producers' cartel and restricting supply through the use of quotas.

Buffer stock schemes

Firstly, we will consider the operation of buffer stock schemes that have existed on and off since the 1920s for a range of commodities including wheat, tin, rubber, coffee, sugar and cocoa. All of these have eventually failed for one reason or another, so there are no prominent examples to consider.

So, what is a buffer stock scheme?

Buffer stock schemes are operated by a central authority (buffer stock agency) and aim to stabilise prices and protect producers from sudden shifts in demand and supply (often supply in the case of agriculture). This is done by the buffer stock agency intervening in the market. If there is too much supply, forcing the price down, the buffer stock agency will increase demand by buying up stocks and price will be pushed up again. If there is a shortage of supply, forcing the price up, the agency will release stocks onto the market forcing the price down. This can, of course, only occur for products that can be stored.

A buffer stock makes use of a price band. Figure 1 below shows the effect of setting up a buffer stock scheme for coffee. If the market is within the two boundaries set by the agency, no action is taken. However, if the market price moves outside the boundaries, the buffer stock operators will intervene.

buffer_stock01

Figure 1 Buffer stock for coffee

If there is a very good harvest of coffee, the supply curve will shift to the right and the price would fall below the boundary. The buffer stock operators would then step in to increase demand to keep the price within the boundary. This is shown in Figure 2 below.

buffer_stock02

Figure 2 Buffer stock - good harvest

The bumper harvest causes the supply curve to shift to S1. This would initially cause the price to fall below the lower boundary to OP1. By buying up stocks, the agency shifts the demand curve to D1 and brings price back within the upper and lower boundaries to OP2.

If there is a poor harvest of coffee, the supply curve will shift to the left and the price would increase above the upper boundary. The buffer stock operators would then step in to increase supply by selling stocks and this would push price down below the upper boundary. This is shown in Figure 3 below:

buffer_stock03

Figure 3 Buffer stock - poor harvest

Problems of a buffer stock scheme

There are a number of possible problems related to buffer stock schemes and these may include:

Cartel arrangements

Such schemes have been attempted in the case of rubber, tin, coffee and sugar, and involve the formation of a single selling organisation, i.e. a cartel, to restrict output of individual members through the issuing of quotas. Thus, when prices need to be increased, members would be ordered to reduce their output in accordance with their quota allocation. This is illustrated in Figure 3 below.

quota

Figure 3 Cartel - use of quotas to restrict output

The supply of primary commodities tends to be perfectly inelastic in the short run, so the cartel requiring a reduction in output would shift the supply curve to the left from S to S1 and raise the price from OP to OP1.

Such schemes have suffered from some of the same problems that have beset buffer stock schemes, i.e. problems of maintaining the cartel and the switch towards substitute goods if prices are kept too high.

Common Agricultural Policy

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\case_study.gif

Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) - subsidies, price floors and buffer stocks

The Common Agricultural Policy was created by the Treaty of Rome in 1957 and introduced in 1962. It was designed to offer minimum guaranteed prices to European farmers to ensure a consistent and reliable supply of food throughout the European community. The historical context was the 'Cold War' and the Berlin crisis and the desire by European Governments to ensure food supplies were maintained and available in times of war and political crisis. However, as political tensions reduced, the CAP essentially became a mechanism to control the production and price of food within the EU, using subsidies as its main policy instrument.

The CAP was based on the economic principle of a 'price floor'. Farmers were guaranteed a price for each unit of output regardless of amount produced; if farmers could double or treble output, they could double or treble their income. When market prices fell below an agreed level, the community intervened to buy surplus farm output. These buffer stocks were supposed to be used in time of food shortages. The CAP certainly helped reduce Europe's reliance on imported food, but in practice, technological advances soon led to massive over-production and the creation of the now legendary 'mountains' and 'lakes' of surplus food and drink. These became so substantial and politically sensitive, that the EU was forced to introduce the concept of 'set-aside' to reduce these large and costly surpluses by paying farmers not to grow certain crops.

Although the concept of the CAP is simple, its operation is not. The CAP has become one of the most controversial European Union policies. Almost 90% of the European Union (EU) land area is considered to be rural in nature, with 26% of the population living there. At one stage nearly three quarters of the entire EU budget was spent on farming. After several reforms this figure has been cut to approximately one third of the budget, but there is still pressure to lower this further as farming only employs 5% of the EU workforce and contributes less than 3% of the total EU Gross Domestic Product.

Supporters of the CAP argue that it helps to ensure affordable food with the average EU household presently devoting 15% of its expenditure to food compared to 30% in 1960. They also maintain that the policy is crucial to sustaining rural communities claiming many farmers would have gone out of business if it were not for EU support.

CAP generates much hostility across Europe. There are many organisations and individuals that oppose the Common Agricultural Policy both in its operation and in principle.

Critics of the CAP identify significant problems, arguing that:

  1. surpluses are a waste of scarce resources
  2. high prices prevent fair trade and make it difficult for farmers in the developing world to compete in EU agricultural markets
  3. inequalities in agriculture are increased
  4. high food prices penalise the poorer members of society
  5. the policy has had damaging effects on the environment as it encourages over-production at the guaranteed price regardless of environmental impacts
  6. many of the surpluses generated are 'dumped' on world markets, distorting those markets and increasing the divide between rich and poor nations further

How EU farm policy hurts poor countries: Daniel Hannan, MEP


Since 2005, farmers are no longer subsidised to maintain production, but instead receive a lump-sum called the Single Farm Payment (SFP) designed to match supply to consumer demand, with farmers now paid for their role as guardians of the countryside.

In May 2008, following a major review by the European Commission, set-aside was abolished with farmers now subsidised to grow crops for biofuels, which are considered more environmentally friendly than fossil fuels. The CAP is due to be reviewed again in 2013 and there is speculation that reforms could shift spending from the CAP towards innovation, climate and energy.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

You may also like to read the following articles:

1.3 Government intervention - questions

In this section are a series of questions on the topic - government intervention. The questions may include various types of questions. For example:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to work through the questions.

Markets - essay

question

Question 1

(a) Explain the role of prices in allocating scarce resources in a market economy.

(b) Discuss the view that that the use of maximum and minimum price controls only serve to distort markets and bring about a misallocation of resources.

Price controls - short answer

question

Question 1

The table below gives the levels of demand and supply for a good.

Price (£) Demand ('000 per month) Supply ('000 per month)
11 - 200
10 30 180
9 60 160
8 90 140
7 120 120
6 150 100
5 180 80
4 210 60
3 240 40
2 270 20
1 300 -


(a) Draw the demand and supply curves on a graph.
(b) What is the equilibrium price and quantity?
(c) If the government supports a minimum price of £10, by how much does supply exceed demand?
(d) If the government controls the price at a maximum of £3, by how much does demand exceed supply?
(e) If the government placed a subsidy of £5 per unit on this good, what would be the new equilibrium price and quantity?
(f) How much would this subsidy cost the government per month?

Question 2

The diagram below represents the market for olives.

ds_ques1

The market for olives

The Italian government decides to protect the production of olives and they agree to set a minimum price. Any olives that are left unsold at the minimum price, the government will buy.

(a) What is the equilibrium price in the absence of any intervention?
(b) If the government set a minimum price of P3, what would be the equilibrium market price?
(c) What would be the level of demand at this price?
(d) If the government set a minimum price of P1, what would be the market price?
(e) What would be the level of olives demanded at this price?
(f) What would be the level of olives supplied at this price?
(g) How many olives would the government have to buy if the minimum price was P1?
(h) Copy the diagram and shade the area that represents the total spending by consumers on olives at a price of P1.
(i) On the same diagram, show the level of government spending on excess olive production.

Price controls - numerical (1)

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_go.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

Question 1

If demand can be shown by a linear demand function of the form Qd = 155 - 10P and supply can be shown by a linear supply function of Qs = -50 + 10P, calculate the quantities demanded and supplied at prices between $1 and $15.

The government puts in place a price ceiling of $8 per unit.

Question 2

What will be the excess demand in the market as a result of the price ceiling?

Question 3

Calculate consumer expenditure:

  1. Before the price ceiling was imposed.
  2. After the price ceiling was imposed.

Question 4

Calculate the firm's revenue:

  1. Before the price ceiling was imposed.
  2. After the price ceiling was imposed.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Price controls - numerical (2)

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

Question 1

If demand can be shown by a linear demand function of the form Qd = 35 - 2P and supply can be shown by a linear supply function of Qs = -20 + 4P, calculate the quantities demanded and supplied at prices between $1 and $15.

The government puts in place a price floor of $8 per unit.

Question 2

What will be the excess supply in the market as a result of the price floor?

Question 3

Calculate consumer expenditure:

  1. Before the price floor was imposed.
  2. After the price floor was imposed.

Question 4

Calculate the firm's revenue (assuming the government purchases the surplus):

  1. Before the price floor was imposed.
  2. After the price floor was imposed.

Question 5

Calculate the amount the government will need to spend to purchase the surplus that arises as a result of the price floor.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating impact of a tax - numerical

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 80 - 5P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -10 + 5P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions.

Question 1

Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $1 - $15.

Question 2

Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.

Question 3

Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.

Question 4

If the government imposes a specific tax per unit of $4, plot the new supply curve on the original supply and demand diagram. Use the diagram to find out the new equilibrium price and quantity.

Question 5

Calculate the tax revenue received by the government.

Question 6

Calculate the revenue received by the firms:

Question 7

Calculate consumer expenditure:

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gif

Calculating impact of a subsidy - numerical

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_start.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\calculator.gif

Assume a linear demand function of the form:

Qd = 160 - 10P

and a linear supply curve of the form:

Qs = -40 + 15P

Using these demand and supply functions, answer the following questions.

Question 1

Calculate the quantities demanded and supplied for prices from $1 - $15.

Question 2

Plot these figures to give the demand and supply curves for the product.

Question 3

Using simultaneous equations, calculate the equilibrium price and output.

Question 4

If the government gives a subsidy per unit of $5, plot the new supply curve on the original supply and demand diagram. Use the diagram to find out the new equilibrium price and quantity.

Question 5

Calculate the amount spent by the government on the subsidy.

Question 6

Calculate the revenue received by the firms:

  1. before the subsidy
  2. after the subsidy

Question 7

Calculate consumer expenditure:

  1. before the subsidy
  2. after the subsidy

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\hl_stop.gif

Agricultural markets - essay

question

Intervention in agricultural markets

Question 1

(a) Agricultural prices tend to fluctuate much more than the price of manufactured goods. Explain how a buffer stock scheme can help overcome this problem.

(b) "Intervention in agricultural markets is always for the good". Do you agree? Justify your answer.

Cheap petrol

Read the article The problem with insanely low petrol prices and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Using diagrams, as appropriate, show how the fuel subsidy in Venezuela affects the market for petrol.

Question 2

Analyse the impact on economic efficiency of the Venezuelan fuel subsidy.

Question 3

Discuss the environmental impact of the Venezuelan fuel subsidy.

World's food system is broken

Read the article World's food system broken, Oxfam warns and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Using diagrams, as appropriate, explain why world food prices have been rising significantly.

Question 2

Examine the likely impact of the increase in food prices on the levels of (a) relative poverty and (b) absolute poverty in the developed and developing world.

Question 3

Analyse the impact of rising food prices on the rate of economic development in the developing world.

Question 4

Discuss two policies that could be adopted by governments and the international community to alleviate the impact of rising food prices.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\reflect.gif\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\find_out.gif

Extension activity

Is the famine in the Horn of Africa, described in these articles and video, a natural disaster or a consequence of man-made economic and political decisions?

Use the following articles and video as a starting point for your investigation.

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Somalia suffering famine, declares UN - video


China plans price controls to curb inflation

Read the article China plans price controls to curb inflation and answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also wish to read the following article to support your answers:


question

Question 1

Define the following terms:

  1. inflation rate
  2. interest rates

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, illustrate the way in which price controls can be used to control food price rises in China.

Question 3

Analyse the impact on consumers of the imposition of price controls on food markets in China.

Question 4

Discuss the role likely effectiveness of price controls as a tool to reduce the level of inflation.

Bolivian fuel shortages

Read the article Bolivia Restores Subsidies for Fuel and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may wish to read the additional following articles to help you answer the questions:


question

Question 1

Using diagrams, as appropriate, explain the reasons for fuel shortages in Bolivia.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, illustrate the impact of Bolivia's fuel subsidies on the market for diesel.

Question 3

Discuss the role of nationalisation in the fuel shortages faced by Bolivia.

Japanese rice subsidies

Read the article Japan rice stockpiles to reach the highest in eight years in 2011 and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Using diagrams, as appropriate, describe the methods used by the Japanese government to protect Japanese rice farmers.

Question 2

Explain the reasons for the decline in demand for rice.

Question 3

Analyse the advantages and disadvantages of these subsidies for (a) consumers, (b) Japanese rice farmers and (c) overseas farmers.

Question 4

Evaluate one other strategy that the Japanese government could use to protect the income levels of their rice farmers.

Coffee shortages in Venezuela

Read the article Venezuelan shoppers face food shortages and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Using supply and demand diagrams, as appropriate, show why there have been coffee shortages in Venezuela.

Question 2

Discuss the effectiveness of price controls as a policy to reduce inflation.

Question 3

Analyse the impact of the price controls on Venezuela's major economic targets.

1.3 Government intervention - simulations and activities

In this section are a series of simulations and activities on the topic - government intervention. These simulations and activities might include:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to move on to the next page.

DragIT - Incidence of tax

In this interaction, drag the end of the demand curve up and down to see the impact of a change in the elasticity of demand on the tax revenue received by the government and the incidence of the tax on the firm and on the consumer. The tax revenue is the sum of the two areas - consumer share and firm share.

In this next interaction, drag the end of the supply curve up and down to see the impact of a change in the elasticity of supply on the tax revenue received by the government and the incidence of the tax on the firm and on the consumer. Again, the tax revenue is the sum of the two areas - firm and consumer.

question

1

Incidence of tax

The more elastic the demand curve the lower the consumers share of the tax will be.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. The more elastic the demand curve, the lower the proportion of the tax is paid by the consumer as the firms are unable to pass the tax on.No, that's not right. The statement is true. The more elastic the demand curve, the lower the proportion of the tax is paid by the consumer as the firms are unable to pass the tax on.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Incidence of tax

The more inelastic the supply curve the lower the producer share of the tax will be.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. The more inelastic the supply curve, the higher the proportion of the tax that is paid by the producer.No, that's not right. The statement is false. The more inelastic the supply curve, the higher the proportion of the tax that is paid by the producer.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

3

Incidence of tax

The more inelastic the demand curve the higher the producer share of the tax will be.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. The more inelastic the demand curve, the lower the proportion of the tax that is paid by the producer as the firms are able to pass the tax on.No, that's not right. The statement is false. The more inelastic the demand curve, the lower the proportion of the tax that is paid by the producer as the firms are able to pass the tax on.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT - Tax revenue

The following interaction illustrates the effects of a change in tax rates on the revenue received by the government. Remember that the effect of a tax is to shift the supply curve upwards by the amount of the tax per unit.

Click on the "S2" label and drag the supply curve S2 to the left and back to see the impact of a change in the level of taxation on the tax revenue.

question

1

Tax revenue

As the tax per unit rises the equilibrium quantity will fall.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. A higher rate of tax will reduce the equilibrium quantity traded in the market.No, that's not right. The statement is true. A higher rate of tax will reduce the equilibrium quantity traded in the market.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT Maximum prices

Government may set a ceiling for prices below the market equilibrium in order to benefit consumers. This is referred to as a 'maximum' price because suppliers are not allowed to charge a higher price. In the UK, the price of a standard loaf of bread was set by the government right up to the early 1970s. Low maximum prices are often used in developing countries as a means of helping the large numbers of urban poor.

Assume that the domestic market price for wheat is £5 (which is also the world price of wheat). In the diagram below drag the 'low maximum price' line to a level that reduces this country's market price of wheat by 20 per cent.

question

1

Maximum prices

In the above situation which of the following will be true? (Select all those statements which are true)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
a) Yes, that's correct. There will be a shortage, but it will be 10,000 tonnes.a) No, that's not right. There will be a shortage, but it will be 10,000 tonnes.b) Yes, that's correct. Original income was £125,000 (£5 × 25,000). New income is £80,000 (£4 × 20,000).b) No, that's not right. Original income was £125,000 (£5 × 25,000). New income is £80,000 (£4 × 20,000).c) Yes, that's correct. Although demand has increased by 20 per cent (from 25,000 to 30,000 tonnes per annum), consumption will fall to 20,000 tonnes as that is all that is being produced (assuming none in store).c) No, that's not right. Although demand has increased by 20 per cent (from 25,000 to 30,000 tonnes per annum), consumption will fall to 20,000 tonnes as that is all that is being produced (assuming none in store).d) Yes, that's correct. Supply would fall from 25,000 to 20,000 tonnes per annum.d) No, that's not right. Supply would fall from 25,000 to 20,000 tonnes per annum.e) Yes, that's correct.e) No, that's not right. The statement is correct.
Check your answer

2

Maximum prices

In the above situation, which of the following will be true? (Select all those statements which are true)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
a) Yes, that's correct. The statement is true.a) No, that's not right. The statement is true.b) Yes, that's correct. The statement is true.b) No, that's not right. The statement is true.c) Yes, that's correct. The statement is true.c) No, that's not right. The statement is true.d) Yes, that's correct. The statement is true.d) No, that's not right. The statement is true.e) Yes, that's correct. The statement is true.e) No, that's not right. The statement is true.
Check your answer

DragIT - Intervention in agricultural markets

Added to the problems of price fluctuations and relative declining income that they have faced, most European farmers have also suffered from growing competition from other food-exporting nations around the world (e.g. USA, Canada, Australia and parts of Africa). One solution to this specific problem would be to set a tariff on all imported products that compete directly with domestic producers.

The following diagram shows the domestic demand and supply for wheat in a given country. The world price of wheat is £3 per tonne (shown by the horizontal red line).

question

1

Import tariff

What will be the level of domestic production at a world price of £3 per tonne?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 15,000 tonnes.No, that's not right. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 15,000 tonnes.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Import tariff

What will be the level of imports at a world price of £3 per tonne?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. It is 35,000 demanded - 15,000 supplied domestically.No, that's not right. It is 35,000 demanded - 15,000 supplied domestically.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

3

Import tariff

What will be the level of imports at a world price of £4 per tonne?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. It is 30,000 demanded - 20,000 supplied domestically.No, that's not right. It is 30,000 demanded - 20,000 supplied domestically.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT - Intervention in agricultural markets (2)

The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has traditionally used high minimum prices as the means of supporting the European farming community.

The following diagram is the same as the one we had before. It shows the demand and supply for wheat in a given country. The world price of wheat is £3 per tonne (shown by the horizontal red line). Given this low price for wheat, domestic production is 15,000 tonnes per annum, yet demand is 35,000 tonnes per annum. As a result this country imports 20,000 tonnes of wheat per annum.

Drag the horizontal red line upwards to represent the setting of a high minimum price that would result in the country now having a surplus of 10,000 tonnes of wheat per annum (a surplus that is then exported).

question

1

Import tariff

What will be the revenue of domestic wheat farmers before the policy change?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 15,000 tonnes. This 15,000 tonnes is sold at £3 per tonne making a total revenue of £45,000.No, that's not right. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 15,000 tonnes. This 15,000 tonnes is sold at £3 per tonne making a total revenue of £45,000.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Import tariff

What will be the price charged after the policy change?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. The new price will be £6. This is the new world price and at this price there will be a surplus of 10,000 tonnes.No, that's not right. The new price will be £6. This is the new world price and at this price there will be a surplus of 10,000 tonnes.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

3

Import tariff

What will be the revenue of domestic wheat farmers after the policy change?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 30,000 tonnes. This 30,000 tonnes is sold at £6 per tonne making a total revenue of £180,000.No, that's not right. Domestic production occurs where the domestic supply curve meets the world price. This is at a quantity of 30,000 tonnes. This 30,000 tonnes is sold at £6 per tonne making a total revenue of £180,000.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

4

Import tariff

How much has consumer expenditure on wheat risen by?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Before the policy change consumers were buying 35,000 tonnes at a price of £3. This meant they were spending £105,000. After the policy change demand falls to 20,000 tonnes, but consumers have to pay the higher price of £6. This means they are now spending £120,000. This gives an increase of £15,000.No, that's not right. Before the policy change consumers were buying 35,000 tonnes at a price of £3. This meant they were spending £105,000. After the policy change demand falls to 20,000 tonnes, but consumers have to pay the higher price of £6. This means they are now spending £120,000. This gives an increase of £15,000.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

5

Import tariff

Assume that as a result of the policy, the world price of wheat has fallen to £2 per tonne, and that the government buys any surplus and then exports it at the world price. What will be the taxpayers contribution to this policy?

a)
b)
c)
d)

Yes, that's correct. To buy the surplus: £6 × 10,000 = £60,000.

Minus export revenues of: £2 × 10,000 = £20,000

equals a net cost of £40,000 (not including any other costs of transporting and storing etc.).

No, that's not right. To buy the surplus: £6 × 10,000 = £60,000.

Minus export revenues of: £2 × 10,000 = £20,000

equals a net cost of £40,000 (not including any other costs of transporting and storing etc.).

Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

1.4 Market failure

In the previous sections we explained markets, the rules of supply and demand, market equilibrium, the price mechanism and market efficiency and how demand and supply are used to calculate market price and plot market equilibrium. We then explained the concepts of elasticity and considered the role and effects of government intervention in the economy. In this section we examine the concept of market failure.

By the end of this section you should be able to:

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\core.gif

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

1.4 Market failure - notes

factory_pollutionMarket failure is a situation in which the free market leads to a misallocation of society's scarce resources in the sense that either overproduction or underproduction of a particular good occurs, leading to a less than optimal outcome.

Reasons for market failure

The reasons for market failure include:

In this section we consider the following topics in detail:

The meaning of externalities

What are externalities?

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Externalities

Externalities are costs (negative externalities) or benefits (positive externalities), which are not reflected in free market prices. Externalities are sometimes referred to as 'by-products', 'spillover effects', 'neighbourhood effects' 'third-party effects' or 'side-effects', as the generator of the externality, either producers or consumers, or both, impose costs or benefits on others who are not responsible for initiating the effect.


car_dumpedThe key feature of an externality is that it is initiated and experienced, not through the operation of the price system, but outside the market.

Proponents of laissez-faire would argue that externalities particularly arise because of the absence of markets - as no markets exist for such things as clean air and seas, beautiful views or tranquillity, economic agents are not obliged to take them into account when formulating their production and consumption decisions, which are based on private costs and benefits i.e. those which are internal to themselves. Another way of putting this is to say individuals have no private property rights over such resources as the air, sea and rivers, and thus ignore them in making their production and consumption decisions.

Property rights refer to those laws and rules that establish rights relating to:

Thus a firm may feel free to dump effluent into a river as the spoiling of the environment and the killing of fish is not a cost that it would directly have to bear. Those on the political left would be more likely to argue that such an externality would arise because of the market system which is based upon the private ownership of resources, with individuals acting in their own self interest and therefore not having to consider what is in the public interest i.e. the problem is due to an absence of communal property rights and of a system of planned production.

Types of externalities

Pollution is an example of an externality which is commonly cited, but it is important to establish at this stage that there are various types of externalities and that they can be classified in different ways: they can arise from acts of consumption or production, and can thus be production, consumption or mixed externalities, and, as previously mentioned they can be experienced as external costs (negative externalities) or as external benefits (positive externalities).

Figure 1 below summarises the different possibilities and provides some examples. It can be seen from this table that there are in fact four different varieties of externality:

A) a production externality: initiated in production and received in production;
B) a mixed externality: initiated in production, but received in consumption;
C) a consumption externality: initiated in consumption and received in consumption;
D) a mixed externality: initiated in consumption, but received in production.

Each of these are sub-divided into two, according to whether they are experienced as an external cost or as an external benefit, giving a total of eight varieties.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\externalities.gif

Figure 1 The various kinds of externality

In practice, the most important externalities are those which affect the environment, and it is these which have received widespread adverse publicity in recent years, and which have prompted the rise of 'green' pressure groups and political parties. Indeed, so great has been the impact of environmental pollution, that in addition to the externalities identified in figure 1, we can also, in a global context, identify externalities which are transmitted from one country to another, and that may be mutually damaging; for example, the Chernobyl nuclear disaster in 1986 in Russia, not only contaminated the local area, but also polluted other parts of Europe; emissions of acid rain from West European nations not only harm the environment in the initiating countries, but also wreak havoc on the forests, lakes and rivers of the Scandinavian countries. The recent earthquake in Japan and the dangerously high levels of radiation is another example of such externalities.

Task 1

Try adding a further example of your own to each of the eight types of externality given in figure 1.

Task 2

Try matching the following examples of externalities to each type of externality in figure 1 (Hint - there is one example of each). Once you have had a go, have a look at our answer to see how you got on.

  1. A person smoking a pipe at a football match causes the person sitting behind to passively smoke.
  2. A large retail organisation attracts numerous extra customers to its store, some of whom spend money in other shops in the vicinity (maybe a shopping mall).
  3. Children are taken to school by car instead of walking or using public transport. This worsens congestion and raises the production costs of firms.
  4. Owner occupiers (people who own their own houses/apartments) in a particular area take measures to increase the value of their properties. Estate agents benefits from the extra commission earned when the houses are sold.
  5. Juggernauts (large trucks/lorries) travel through inner city areas, causing traffic congestion for other commercial road users that raises their production costs.
  6. A power station emits black fumes into the air that discolours the paintwork of nearby houses.
  7. Farmers provide pathways in the countryside that benefit walkers.
  8. A private gardener plants an assortment of beautiful plants in her front garden and enhances the environment for her neighbours and passers-by.

Task 2 - suggested answers

How do externalities affect allocative efficiency?

chemical_plant01Given the existence of perfect competition, allocative efficiency would automatically occur where price equals marginal cost in all markets, assuming that neither negative nor positive externalities are present.

So, how do externalities affect our condition for efficiency? Let's consider case of a firm which discharges its waste products into a river. Such a firm would be treating the environment as a free resource, and would be imposing a cost on society as a whole, rather than just on the consumers of the good. The price charged to consumers would not therefore, in this instance, reflect the true cost of the product; if the firm were compelled to install equipment which could treat its effluent and render it harmless to the environment, its production costs and prices would rise and consumers would, as a consequence, reduce their demand for the product in question. Resources would then be reallocated to other lines of production.

In this case there is a divergence between private and social cost.

Similarly, if the firm's production decisions were to generate positive externalities, such as the beneficial effects arising from the provision of employment, then there would be a divergence between private and social benefit.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Social cost

Social cost is the private, internal cost plus the value of negative externalities.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Social benefit

Social benefit is the private, internal benefits plus the value of positive externalities.


Now, the significance of this analysis is that allocative inefficiency will occur if private cost or benefit diverges from social cost or benefit. Where externalities exist the condition for allocative efficiency is that price = social marginal cost = social marginal benefit i.e. the price must equal the true marginal cost of production to society as a whole, rather than just the private marginal cost.

We will now illustrate the above in relation to the firm discharging waste into the river.

Hence externalities cause market failure:

Negative externalities of production


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Negative externalities of consumption


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

The economic theory of traffic congestion

Figure 1 below shows how the analysis of externalities that we looked at in the previous section can be applied to the problems of traffic congestion.

congestion

Figure 1 Road transport, congestion and economic theory

Economic theory can be used to analyse the issues involved in traffic congestion as shown here. Figure 1 indicates the relationship between the cost of travel and the flow of traffic along a particular route. The essence of this theory is based on the fact that, when making a journey by car, a motorist only considers the marginal private cost (MPC). This is the cost directly attributable to him/herself, such as time, fuel and the maintenance of the vehicle, rather than the full cost of the journey, which may include costs imposed on society such as pollution, noise and time lost due to congestion. When added to the private costs, these are termed the marginal social costs (MSC), the difference between the two representing the externality imposed by the motorist.

congestion_toy_carsIn outlining the theory, it is assumed that, when making a journey, congestion is the only externality. The graph represents the demand for travel along a particular stretch of road over a period of time. Up to a flow of traffic F0, there is no congestion, thus there is no divergence between MPC and MSC, although in reality, such a situation only applies to extremely low volumes of traffic.

As the flow of traffic increases above F0, congestion is apparent and there is a divergence between MSC and MPC. Note that the MSC is equal to the MPC, plus the social cost of congestion.

If the demand for travel on this particular route is of the normal shape (represented by D on the graph) and is a measure of the marginal benefit, then the flow of traffic will be determined by the intersection of the demand curve and the MPC curve at F1 and the private cost to the motorist will be b. At a flow of F1, the external cost, not taken into account by the motorist, is ab (the difference between the MPC and MSC). This means that resources are not being allocated efficiently and that individuals are making more journeys than they would if they were aware of the full social costs.


www

To get some up to date examples on traffic congestion, try searching the Biz/ed In the News archive. You can do this in the window below.

Try searching on terms like:


Demerit goods

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\no_smoking.jpgWhat are demerit goods?

Demerit goods are goods which are deemed to be socially undesirable, and which are likely to be over-produced and over-consumed through the market mechanism. Examples of demerit goods are cigarettes, alcohol and all other addictive drugs such as heroine and cocaine.

The problem arises from the fact that so long as an effective demand is present, such goods are, in all probability, going to be extremely profitable to produce, and this is all that a price system takes into account - the market neither possesses a 'heart' to enable it to help those in need, nor is it inherently able to make value judgements about which commodities are good or bad for society as a whole: it is prices and profits which act as the 'guiding light' to resource allocation.

However, the consumption of demerit goods imposes considerable negative externalities on society as a whole, such that the private costs incurred by the individual consumer are less than the social costs experienced by society in general; for example, cigarette smokers not only damage their own health, but also impose a cost on society in terms of those who involuntarily passively smoke and the additional cost to the National Health Service in dealing with smoking-related diseases. Thus, the price that consumers pay for a packet of cigarettes is not related to the social costs to which they give rise i.e. the marginal social cost will exceed the market price and overproduction and over-consumption will occur, causing a misallocation of society's scarce resources. This is illustrated in figure 1 below.

demerit_good

Figure 1 Over-consumption of a demerit good

The diagram illustrates how the market fails in the case of demerit goods. At a market price of OP, OQ quantity of the demerit good is consumed, where demand (private marginal benefit) equals supply (private marginal cost). However, at OQ the social marginal cost exceeds the price by the vertical distance XY, the value of the marginal external cost. Social optimality would require a smaller level of consumption at OQ1, where price = social marginal cost = social marginal benefit.

Government responses - demerit goods

Possible government responses to correct market failure arising from demerit goods

Less severe regulatory controls might take the form of spatial restrictions e.g. people may be disbarred from smoking in their place of work, on public transport and in cinemas and restaurants; there may be time restrictions in that it may be illegal to sell alcohol during certain periods of the day, or there may be age restrictions in terms of a minimum age being stipulated at which young people are permitted to buy cigarettes and alcohol.

Possible government responses to externalities

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\congestion_charge.jpgThe outstanding characteristic of a market economy is that production does not occur as a result of some grand, master plan; rather, it is the result of the pulls and pushes of supply and demand, of the numerous uncoordinated decisions of individuals and firms. As individuals are assumed to seek to maximise their own satisfaction, and firms their own profits, decisions made are likely to be strictly on the basis of private costs and benefits, and, as previously explained, herein lies the problem: unless the full social costs and benefits of production and consumption decisions are taken into account, so that MSC is equated to MSB, social inefficiency and a misallocation of society's scarce resources will result.

So, what measures can a government take to rectify such inefficiency, and how successful is it likely to be? As is the case with most important questions in economics, a range of answers is possible, depending largely on the political perspective of the respondent. At one end of the spectrum, governments could 'leave well alone', essentially not interfering with markets but trying to gently persuade firms and individuals to modify their behaviour. At the other extreme, the market could be completely replaced by direct government provision, and in between various policy options are possible. We now turn to an examination of some of these options.

In practice it is the problem of production externalities, particularly environmental ones, which most occupy the attention of governments, and our discussion will mainly, but not exclusively, focus on these.

The main measures that governments can take will be considered in the next few sections and include:

Perhaps there is one more alternative - the use of 'nudge theory', rather than coercion, to persuade people to change their behaviour.


C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Changing behaviour with a gentle nudge

Can a nudge replace a congestion tax?


Direct government provision

Direct provision of goods and services by the government

S:\pictures\economics_business\bus_london.jpgThe existence of externalities provides an important argument for the common ownership, or nationalisation of a number of key industries.

The argument is that privately owned firms, in order to survive in a competitive world, necessarily have to put their own interests before those of society at large, for to do otherwise might be inconsistent with the goal of long run profit maximisation, or even survival. This harsh reality of the market is likely to manifest itself in the generation of negative externalities such as pollution, as the control of these externalities would involve higher costs and an adverse impact on profits; conversely, production activity which conferred net positive externalities on society might not be undertaken in sufficient quantities if the criterion of private profitability could not be met.

Nationalised industries, on the other hand, which, on account of being commonly owned, could be operated according to broad social criteria, rather than the narrow commercial one of private profitability, and this allows for the possibility of externalities to be fully incorporated into production decisions. Thus, for example, questions of workers' safety standards and atmospheric pollution could be accorded priority status, rather than being ignored on the grounds that to do otherwise would adversely affect profits and competitiveness; and activities such as the keeping open of 'uneconomic' coal mines and the provision of postal and transport services to remote outlying areas, could all be maintained on the grounds that they provide substantial positive externalities to society at large, although not necessarily being profitable in the sense that the private revenues from such activities exceed the private costs.

Similarly, an important argument for merit goods such as education and health being directly provided by the government rather than through the market, is that they not only confer private benefits on individuals but also significant positive externalities on society as a whole which individuals would tend to ignore when making their consumption decisions. As a result, left to the market, under-provision is likely to occur; for example, individuals would be prepared to buy education through the market if they had to, as substantial private benefits, such as higher life-time earnings, are likely to result. However, a case for a higher level of government provision can be made on the grounds that not all the benefits accrue solely to the individual - society gains from a more efficient and adaptable labour force and perhaps a more tolerant and more aware population. The topic of such merit goods will be considered in more detail.

The above arguments for direct government provision would of course be strongly contested by free market economists who would argue the case for privatisation, the desirability of using markets to provide merit goods and the extremely poor record of pollution control of the formerly centrally planned economies of Eastern Europe.

Extension of property rights

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\house.jpgProperty rights concern the legal entitlement to property and the right to use or sell the property, as well as the rights that other people have, or do not have, over the property. It is argued that negative externalities in particular arise because of the existence of incomplete property rights over natural resources such as air, land, rivers and seas i.e. as property rights are not fully allocated to these areas as nobody really owns them, individuals and firms are free to impose external costs from their production and consumption activities without having to pay any compensation. The dumping of toxic wastes into the sea and the riding of a noisy motorbike provide two examples.

Thus by extending property rights individuals would be able to stop others imposing costs on them or to claim compensation if they did so. A person purchasing a house, for example, could also acquire a set of 'amenity' rights that would entitle the owner to peace and quiet in the vicinity of the property as well as a supply of water and air of a reasonable quality. Any infringement of such rights e.g. by neighbours playing music unduly loudly, or trucks emitting excessive exhaust fumes into the air, would give the owner of the amenity rights entitlement to compensation. In this case the externality would be internalised as the initiators of the external costs would be forced to pay for them, and adjust their production/consumption decisions to more socially efficient levels.

However, there may be a number of problems with this solution in practice:


Buying the rainforest

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\vodcast.gif

The following is a trailer for a series called 'I bought a rainforest'.


More extracts for this series can be found on YouTube.

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\find_out.gif

Can you find successful examples where extending property rights has resulted in a reduction of negative externalities?

Taxes and subsidies

The use of taxes and subsidies to tackle the problem of externalities is a market-based method of control as it works through the price system, i.e. through the impact of changes in prices.

If negative externalities exist, and there is allocative inefficiency at the free market price because SMC is greater than price and overproduction is occurring, then the appropriate solution would be to tax the good; if, on the other hand, the market is under-producing because positive externalities are not being taken into account, it would be appropriate for the government to grant a subsidy.

Taxes

taxThere are two types of tax which may be applied to address the problem of negative externalities: a tax set equal to each firm's marginal external costs and an environmental or 'green' tax.

The policy of taxing firms according to the marginal external costs that they impose on society can be illustrated using figure 1 below. In this example we assumed that a firm was dumping waste products into a river. The government would have to assess the cost to society of such an action, and impose a tax on the offending firm equal to the value of the marginal external cost (or negative externality); in this case the tax would internalise the externality by making the polluter pay. The levying of such a tax would shift the supply curve from S to S1,which would increase the market price to OP1, and cause the level of output to fall to OQ1, where P = SMC and allocative efficiency is achieved.

ext_neg_prod_1

Figure 1 Negative externalities - dumping of waste

An environmental tax could be imposed either on a product responsible for creating pollution, or on the inputs to an industry which have caused environmental damage e.g. carbon producing fuels, which are believed to play the major role in the process of global warming. The aim of a carbon tax on each unit of carbon in fossil fuels would be to: raise the price of those sources of power with high carbon contents, thus encouraging a switching to power sources causing lower CO2 emissions; encourage greater conservation of energy in general; and stimulate the search for more environmentally-friendly technologies.

Issues arising from the tax/subsidy approach

Advocates of this approach would argue that it permits the forces of demand and supply to operate. At the same time generators of negative externalities are induced to 'clean-up their act' because the less pollution they create, the less their tax liability; and conversely, grants and subsidies encourage greater output and consumption of those goods involving net social benefits.

In practice various difficulties are likely to arise:

Tradeable pollution rights

Like the use of taxes and subsidies, tradeable pollution rights (otherwise known as tradeable emission allowances or permits), represent another market-based solution to the problem of negative externalities, in particular pollution. They were first introduced in the USA in 1990 under the Clean Air Act in which the Environmental Protection Agency set a target rate of reduction for power stations' emissions of sulphur dioxide. Initially, power stations were issued with emission permits in proportion to their current pollution levels and were allowed to discharge pollution into the air up to a specified limit. Thereafter, those power stations for whom the cost of reducing pollution was low, could sell their spare pollution permits to generators for whom the cost of pollution abatement, through the installation of appropriate equipment, would be very high. Thus, a market in tradeable pollution rights is created, stimulating pollution reduction through the possibility of making money out of selling surplus permits.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Tradeable pollution rights

Tradeable pollution rights are emission allowances or permits which can be traded between organisations whose operations generate pollution.


elec_pylon_view_upThe main argument in favour of such a scheme is that it operates through the market via the price system: firms are given a profit incentive, i.e. through the right to sell spare permits, to find cheap ways of reducing their pollution levels; and such a system should be administratively cheap and simple to implement , as the regulatory agency need have no information regarding firms' costs - it simply has to issue the permits and arrange for their sale; in addition, consumers may benefit if the extra profits made by low pollution power stations, arising from the sale of their spare permits to other companies, are passed on in the form of lower prices.

The main argument against the use of tradeable emission permits is that they do not actually stop firms from polluting the environment; they only provide an incentive to so - where a degree of monopoly power and relatively inelastic demand exist, the extra cost of purchasing additional permits so as to further pollute the atmosphere, could easily be offset by the possibility of charging consumers higher prices; moreover, the system of allocating permits in accordance to existing emission levels could be seen as a reward for the greatest polluters!


www

To get some up to date examples on tradeable permits, try searching the Biz/ed In the News archive. You can do this in the window below.


Regulation, legislation and direct controls

sign_noIn practice the use of direct controls represents the most common approach to pollution abatement. Such controls can be applied both to individuals and firms and can take a number of forms; for example, restrictions can be imposed on smoke emissions from private homes and firms; restrictions may be placed on all forms of building in designated green-belt areas; minimum environmental standards may be stipulated for air and water quality; laws may be passed to prevent drinking and driving and the sale of alcohol and tobacco to people under a certain age.

Apart from restriction, direct controls can also be used more severely: activities generating negative externalities could be banned completely; for instance, the dumping of waste into rivers or the sea; or an activity which conferred net positive externalities on society could be made compulsory; for example, all children under the age of 16 in the country could be made by law to receive some form of education, whether it be in a state school, a private school or at home.

The main advantage of regulation is that it is the most direct way of tackling the problem of externalities; for example, market-based solutions such as taxes and tradeable emission permits provide incentives to firms to reduce their pollution levels but do not compel them to do so; as such problems as global warming and the depletion of the ozone layer are thought by many to threaten the very survival of our planet, it is argued that we cannot afford to trust our futures with policies which allow for the possibility of non-compliance. Providing legal restrictions are backed by inspections that are sufficiently regular and rigorous, they should be effective.

Against this, it is argued that in reality the policing of regulations can present great difficulties as the less environmentally conscious firms may attempt to circumvent the controls e.g. through the generation of pollution during the night. Thus an extremely large number of inspectors might have to be employed to ensure compliance.

It is also claimed that regulation can be a rather blunt, indiscriminate instrument of control; for example the setting of maximum emission limits does not take into account the fact that the cost of reducing pollution would vary considerably as between different firms, some facing high costs with others facing low costs. Thus a uniform limit applied to all firms would be an inefficient way of reducing pollution, implying as it would a high resource cost. Also it may be the case that once emission targets have been achieved, there would be no further incentive to continue to reduce pollution, as would be the case with a pollution tax.

Regulation may also give rise to the problem of regulatory capture - those being regulated may be successful in manipulating the regulatory body to act in accordance with the private interests of the firms concerned, rather than in the interests of society as a whole.

Positive externalities of production


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Positive externalities of consumption


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Merit goods

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\fire_engine.jpgWhat are merit goods?

Merit goods are the opposite of demerit goods - they are goods which are deemed to be socially desirable, and which are likely to be under-produced and under-consumed through the market mechanism. Examples of merit goods include education, health care, welfare services, housing, fire protection, refuse collection and public parks.

In contrast to pure public goods, merit goods could be, and indeed are, provided through the market, but not necessarily in sufficient quantities to maximise social welfare. Thus goods such as education and health care are provided by the state, but there is also a parallel, thriving private sector provision. Indeed, there is considerable disagreement between economists on the right and left of the political spectrum over the extent to which such goods should be provided by the state or the private sector. We consider these arguments later in this section.

question

Before we proceed with our discussion of merit goods, and in particular the question of why merit goods tend to be underprovided by the market, it would be useful at this stage to summarise the main differences between public goods, private goods and merit goods. Have a go at filling in the blank table below (we have put in a few entries to help you along). Once you have had a go, follow the link under the table to compare your answers with ours.

Main features Public goods Merit goods Private goods
Diminishability (non-rivalry) Non-diminishable (non-rivalry)
Excludability Excludable
Benefits Individual and communal (strong positive externalities)
Provider Usually private enterprise
Financed by Usually taxation
Examples


Main features of public, merit and private goods - full table

Why might merit goods be underprovided by the market?


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Government responses - merit goods

Possible government responses to the under-provision of merit goods

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\government_legal.jpgOne solution would be for the government to play no role whatsoever and to allow the provision of merit goods to be decided completely through the free interaction of market forces. However, for all the reasons previously mentioned, this would lead to extreme under-provision of these goods and a misallocation of resources from the standpoint of society as a whole. Thus, in practice, governments play a substantial role in the provision of merit goods such as health and education, even where they are ideologically committed, as the present Conservative government is, to the market system. However, the exact form that such government involvement should take is a subject of much dispute, and we shall consider each of the following in turn:

Direct government provision

Traditionally in Western Europe the overwhelming majority of health care and education is still paid for out of general taxation and provided free at the point of contact by the government - for most people, when they visit their doctor, go to hospital, school or college, no direct charge is levied upon them; the private sector still only accounts for a relatively small proportion of all health and education provision. Apart from generating substantial positive externalities and overcoming the problems arising from unequal income distribution, lack of current and future information and potential private monopoly power, direct government provision may also give rise to large economies of scale, and may thus be productively efficient; for example, when a service such as health care is provided to the population as a whole, greater scale economies are likely to arise in terms of capital and labour costs than could be expected to accrue to the private health care sector, whose scale of operations is necessarily much smaller than that of the NHS.

However, the idea of universal provision for all on the basis of need, with prices and profits playing no role, is one which sits very uneasily with the philosophy of market economics, and has thus in recent years come under fierce attack from right-wing, market-oriented economists. They have argued that government provision of health and education has led to an undesirable situation of state monopoly power in these areas and that to increase consumer choice, lower costs and raise the level of efficiency, greater competition is required.

Regulation

The government may also use a range of regulatory devices both to increase the consumption of merit goods and to ensure their quality. In the case of education, it may be compulsory that all children between the ages of 5-16 receive some form of schooling, be it in the private or public sector, and quality is controlled in such ways as school teachers being required to have stipulated qualifications before they are allowed to teach. In the case of health care, vaccinations against various contagious diseases could be made compulsory and medical practitioners such as doctors, dentists, opticians and nurses could be required to obtain certain qualifications before they can practice. The government could also use regulation to enforce the consumption of a good provided by the private sector which is deemed to be a merit good by virtue of the positive externalities that it generates: the compulsory consumption of seat-belts by motorists provides one such example.

In the case of housing, the use of rent controls on private sector rented accommodation are a means by which the market can be regulated so as to protect tenants from having to pay high rents.

Rent controls represent a form of price fixing. More specifically, they represent an attempt to fix a maximum price below the equilibrium i.e. a maximum rent that a private landlord may charge for rented accommodation; and, to be effective, rent controls may also have to be accompanied by further regulation preventing the landlord from ousting the tenant once the rent has been fixed. Figure 1 below illustrates the fixing of such a maximum, and the possible longer term problems

rent_control

Figure 1 The use of rent controls

The diagram shows that, with a relatively inelastic supply of rented accommodation, the free market rent would be established at a price of OP, with the quantity demanded and supplied equal at OQ. However, if the government impose a ceiling of OP1 on the price that landlords can charge, an initial shortage of Q1Q2 develops as the short term profitability of renting-out accommodation declines. In the longer term , if landlords' rate of return falls below what they could receive from alternative investments, such as government bonds, then existing landlords could be expected to leave the housing market with little new rented accommodation coming onto it. As a consequence, the supply of rented accommodation would shift from S to S1, and the shortage would increase to Q3Q2. Thus, unless the government could shift the supply curve to the right, for example by building more publicly owned council houses, the long term shortage would worsen, with the existing rent-controlled stock descending into an ever greater state of disrepair, as a result of landlords seeking to reduce their costs by postponing or cancelling repair and maintenance work.

The use of taxes and subsidies to tackle the problem of externalities is a market-based method of control as it works through the price system, i.e. through the impact of changes in prices.

If negative externalities exist, and there is allocative inefficiency at the free market price because SMC is greater than price and overproduction is occurring, then the appropriate solution would be to tax the good; if, on the other hand, the market is under-producing because positive externalities are not being taken into account, it would be appropriate for the government to grant a subsidy. We shall consider each in turn:

Subsidies

Subsidies may be used to increase the output of merit goods, provided both by the private and public sectors, to the socially optimum level.

For example, the theatre is usually provided by the private sector, and is often regarded as a merit good on account of the educative and civilising benefits that it confers on society. The government might take the view that without state assistance to the arts, there would be an unacceptably small number of theatres able to survive. Figure 2 illustrates how the subsidy would operate.

merit_subsidy

Figure 2 The effect of subsidising a merit good

In the diagram, the free market price of theatre tickets is established by the intersection of the curves D and S at OP, with the equilibrium quantity at OQ. A government subsidy, equivalent to the vertical distance XY, would have the effect of shifting the supply curve to the right, causing the market price to fall to OP1 and the quantity of theatre tickets demanded and supplied to increase to OQ1. Consumers' expenditure on the theatre increases from OPZQ to OP1YQ1 and the area P1RXY represents the total amount that the government spends on the subsidy.

In the case of health care in several West European countries, the majority of it is provided free to the user out of general taxation, although charges may be levied for prescriptions and optical and dental treatment. In these cases the prices charged have been made cheaper than they would otherwise be, with patients only paying part of the cost of treatment and the government making up the difference through the payment of subsidies to suppliers. In the case of housing, owner occupiers receive a subsidy through the receipt of tax relief on mortgage interest repayments, which is not available to those people who rent their accommodation. State education like health care, may be provided without direct charges being made, although education vouchers represent an alternative form of market-based, subsidised provision which has been proposed.

For a subsidy to work, the government would have to assess the value of the marginal external benefit (i.e. the positive externality) to society and give a subsidy equivalent to this amount.


eg

If the good in question were loft insulation which confers benefits on society in terms of energy conservation, households prepared to lag their lofts could be given a grant, and this would shift the demand curve D=PMB to the right to D1=SMB. Allocative efficiency is achieved as SMB = SMC at OQ1. A similar result could be achieved by subsidising the output of loft insulation which would cause the supply curve to shift to the right until the socially optimum level of production is reached.

ext_pos_cons_1

Figure 3 Positive externalities - loft insulation

Public goods

What are public goods?

lighthouse_portland01Pure public goods are ones that when consumed by one person can be consumed in equal amounts by the remainder of society, and where the possibility of excluding others from consumption is impossible.

Examples of public goods are:

It is likely that the market, left to itself, will seriously under-produce such goods, or possibly not produce them at all. This is because the market will only provide goods for which a profit can be made, and pure public goods possess two important properties that together make their production on the basis of private profitability extremely difficult. These features are:

Firstly, consider the characteristic of non-rivalry: this means that one person's use of the public good does not deprive any other person of such use or does not diminish the amount available to others; for example, if one person enjoys the benefits of being protected by the police-force, a flood control dam or the national defence system, it does not prevent everyone else doing the same; similarly, if one person benefits from walking along a street at night-time which is paved, free of pot-holes, and well-lit, the benefits and the availability to others would not be diminished.

Secondly, consider the characteristic of non-excludability: this means that when the public good is provided to one person, it is not possible to prevent others from enjoying its consumption - sometimes summarised as: provision at all means provision for all. For example, if a police force, a flood-control dam or a national defence system is successful in offering protection to citizens of a country, once it has been provided it is impossible to exclude anyone within the country from consuming and benefiting from them. Similarly, for a paved and well-lit public street, nobody can be prevented from enjoying its benefits.


The concept of a 'public good' can perhaps best be understood by comparing it with its opposite, a private good.

A private good possesses two features, excludability and rivalry, and when consumed by one person, it is not available to others; thus, a person buying a new washing machine can exercise private property rights over it and exclude others from enjoying its cleaning abilities, whilst, at the same time, diminishing the total stock of washing machines available for sale to others.


Thus, in the case of public goods,the market fails because the private sector would be unwilling to supply them - their non-excludabilty makes them non-marketable, because non-payers cannot be prevented from enjoying the benefits of consumption, and therefore prices cannot be attributed to particular consumers. This involves the free-rider problem, which arises when it is impossible to provide a good or service to some without it automatically and freely being available to others who do not contribute to its cost. For example, imagine a situation in which you shared an island with five other inhabitants; if you paid privately for an army to defend the island against violent invaders, your five co-inhabitants could 'free-ride' off you by enjoying the benefits of the defence, without having to pay anything towards it; there would probably come a point when you would withdraw your payments and, like the others, leave it to someone else to foot the bill; eventually, the army would not be provided at all.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Free riders

Free riders are those who enjoy the benefits of a public good without having to pay, because it is impossible to exclude them.


Hence, in a free market, a whole range of pure public goods may not be provided, and the only answer is for the state to provide them, financed out of general taxation. Moreover, the non-rivalry aspect of public goods means that the cost of supplying one more user i.e. the marginal cost, is zero; for example, once paving stones have been laid, it makes no difference how many people walk along them as there is no additional cost involved. As the condition for the achievement of allocative efficiency is that price should be set equal to marginal cost, it would therefore follow that to achieve an optimum level of output and consumption of public goods the state should provide them at zero prices.

Non-pure public goods (quasi-public goods)

tollIn practice, various ways may be devised for excluding free riders from the consumption of public goods, as the characteristics of non-excludabilty and non-rivalry may not be completely present. In such cases, the goods would be referred to as non-pure or quasi-public goods; for example, in the case of a motorway, various methods could be used, such as electronic tagging or toll-gates, to make users pay (an impossibility with a pure public good), so excludabilty would be possible; and, if the motorway were to become sufficiently congested, non-rivalry would not be present i.e. as the road reaches its full vehicle capacity, as often happens in the rush-hour periods on urban motorways, each extra road user does reduce the availability of the motorway to other motorists and raises the marginal supply cost above zero. (The marginal cost would of course be zero, or near to zero, on an entirely uncongested motorway.)

Thus a non-pure public good is an example of a mixed good, which is one which has both a public and a private good content. A motorway provides an example of a public good with a private good component, and conversely it is possible to identify private goods, with a public good component e.g. driving a car is an act of private consumption, but when public transport is not available, perhaps because transport workers are on strike, car owners may offer lifts to stranded travellers creating some publicness. Hence, in practice, many public and private goods contain some mix of both.

Common access resources & sustainability

Common access resources

Common access, or common pool resources (CAR/CPR), are natural resources including forests and pastures, fisheries, oil and gas fields, national parks, grazing lands and irrigation systems, which are characterised by the difficulty of excluding people from using them. As a result of the inability to charge a price for their use, over-consumption, degradation and depletion of these resources is a likely outcome. Indeed, the use by one individual or group of the resource will mean that less of that resource is available for use by others. This distinguishes common access resources from pure public goods, which exhibit both non-excludability andnon-rivalry in consumption.

It is argued that the lack of a price mechanism for common access resources results in their overuse, depletion and degradation. The consequence of the actions of producers and consumers, who do not pay for the resources they use, creates a threat to sustainability and, therefore, the availability of common access resources for future generations.

The origin of the study of common access resources dates back to medieval land tenure in Europe, where herders were entitled to graze their cows on common parcels of land for free. The result was over-grazing and the degradation of the land. The problem was described and analysed by Garrett Hardin in his article 'The Tragedy of the Commons', which appeared in the Science journal in 1968. Hardin explained that it was in each herder's interest to put any additional cows he acquired onto the grazing land, even if the quality of the common was damaged for the whole community. This was considered to be a rational economic decision by the individual herder, because each additional cow added to the individual's 'marginal utility', while the damage to the common land was shared by the entire group. However, the consequence of these individual rational economic decisions was market failure because these actions resulted in the degradation, depletion or even destruction of the resource to the detriment of all users and, therefore, society in general.

The tragedy of the Commons

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif



The overgrazing cost shown in Hardin's analogy is an example of a negative externality of consumption, where the private utility is diminished by the negative utility suffered by third parties; in this case the other herders. The grazing land is over-consumed and so there is a welfare loss.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\ext_neg_cons_f.png

To reduce these negative externalities, Hardin suggests potential management solutions for common goods including privatisation, environmental taxation, government regulation and stricter management by the state. The nature of this regulation depends on whether the resources are within national boundaries or global in nature. Where national resources are concerned; rules on their use can be imposed by national governments. Global common access resources, such as fishing grounds, will require the creation of international regulatory organisations to control their use. Hardin also suggests the transfer of common access resources to private ownership. In keeping with his original pasture analogy, he categorises this as the enclosure of the commons.

The 'Tragedy of the Commons' is an analogy. The major theme running through Hardin's work is, in fact, the growth of human populations with the Earth's resources being a general 'common'. He focuses on the allocation and exploitation of larger resources, such as the Earth's atmosphere and oceans, and the 'negative commons' of pollution.


C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Garrett Hardin on the Tragedy of the Commons and Resources

In this video, Garrett Hardin is interviewed on the Tragedy of the Commons and Resource Allocation: As Hardin says:

C:\Users\Paul\Documents\IB Business\UNITS\quotation.gif

The Tragedy of the Commons is concerned with the allocation of resources...The unmanaged commons cannot possibly work once the population gets about a certain size.


Common access resources in practice

In practice neither the state nor the market has been uniformly successful in solving common access resource problems.

Indeed, Hardin's Common's Theory has been criticised by a number of economists, not least by Elinor Ostrom the political economist and the 2009 Nobel Memorial Prize winner in Economic Sciences. Together with colleague Oliver E. Williams, Ostrom's analysed economic governance, especially those related to common access resources or 'the commons'.

Ostrom simulated conflicts concerning the allocation of the commons and derived a complex theoretical framework that went beyond the simple analysis of private costs and benefits. She focused on additional variables, such as community, leadership, trust and collaboration in resource sustainability and claimed it is not necessary to have a 'top-down' management system regulated by the state.

Ostrom's extensive research includes analysis of complex fishing systems in Nova Scotia, irrigation systems in the Philippines and Sri Lanka and groundwater usage in California. Her research results suggest that sustainability is possible if the users of resources collaborate to create democratically agreed, and adaptable, rules for the exploitation of common access resources, with community sanctions if these rules are broken. She argues that local communities make better decision about the use of community resources than governments or private organisations, because they have access to more information about the local context and are directly affected. Her conclusions are supported by empirical data showing that local-level monitoring of resources and community self-determination is effective in ensuring resource sustainability.

The following videos explain Ostrom's beliefs and report on her Nobel Prize award:


C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Sustainable Development and the Tragedy of Commons


First woman to receive Nobel prize in economics



Other critics of Hardin's 'Tragedy of the Commons' analysis, focus on his proposal to transfer common goods into the hands of private owners. Professor Heller of the Columbia Law School, for example, coined the term 'Tragedy of the Anticommons' to describe a situation in which rational individuals, acting separately, collectively waste a common resource by under-utilising it. Heller believes that the existence of numerous private rights holders may frustrate the achievement of socially desirable outcomes. Supporters of this theory claim that too many property rights, such as patents, leads to reduced innovation. Competing patents in biomedical research illustrates a situation where useful and affordable products are prevented from reaching the market and adding to social welfare.

Sustainability

A universally accepted definition of sustainability remains elusive, because they focus on the many contexts in which the term is used. Most relevant to the study of market failure are those definitions that relate to natural resources and their usage.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Sustainability and sustainable development

Sustainability encompasses the simple principle of taking from the earth only what it can provide indefinitely, thus leaving future generations no less than we have access to ourselves.

Friends of the Earth, Scotland

Sustainability may be described as our responsibility to proceed in a way that will sustain life and allow our children, grandchildren and great-grandchildren to live comfortably in a friendly, clean, and healthy world.

Thomas Jefferson Sustainability Council

Sustainable Development is positive change which does not undermine the environmental or social systems on which we depend. It requires a coordinated approach to planning and policy making that involves public participation. Its success depends on widespread understanding of the critical relationship between people and their environment and the will to make necessary changes.

Unesco


All these definitions concern the need for humans to:

Sustainable development was defined at the 2005 World Summit as development requiring an understanding and reconciliation of the 'three pillars' of sustainability, that of environmental, social and economic demands.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

The Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) are international development goals that all 193 United Nations member states agreed to achieve by the year 2015 following the Millennium Summit in 2000. There are eight goals with 21 targets. Goal 7 is to ensure environmental sustainability with the target of integrating the principles of sustainable development into country policies and programmes to reverse the loss of environmental resources. Each year the United Nations reports on progress towards achieving the MDGs. The following articles provide details on achievements and failures to meet the MDGs and, in particular, progress towards environmental sustainability.

Threats to Sustainability

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\business management\student_packs\articulate_interactions\images\environment_globe.jpgThe threat to sustainability comes from the unplanned and often unfettered exploitation of the world's natural resources. The increase in globalisation, the drive for economic growth, population growth and developments in technology has made the need for management of global common access resources more acute, whether this is by governments or by local communities.

Clearly, there are already many examples of threats to sustainability from the depletion and destruction of common access resources, such as deforestation, soil erosion and the overfishing of oceans. These are compounded by the pursuit of economic growth by newly developing countries, and in less economically developed countries where high levels of poverty and poor regulation creates negative externalities through over-exploitation of land for agriculture.

The depletion of natural resources, such as fossil fuels and fishing resources, creates individual hardship and political instability and potentially threatens world peace. Resource depletion is accelerating and the economic growth of countries that ignore this trend will be eroded by higher commodity prices.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

The Earth Summit 2012 on Sustainable Development - 'Rio+20'

Read the article Big summit seeks big idea. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the link above to read the article in a separate window.


The threat to sustainability from the use of fossil fuels

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\fossil_fuel_environment.jpgMarket failure exists when the production or use of a good or service results in an externalities and welfare loss, because the market does not direct an efficient amount of resources into the production, distribution, or consumption of a good.

Fossil fuels are non-renewable resources as they take millions of years to form and accelerating overuse is leading to their rapid depletion. The principles of supply and demand mean that as fossil fuel supplies diminish, prices rise. However, since the producers and consumers of fossil fuels do not have to account to later generations for their overexploitation of resources, fossil fuels are over-produced, and over-consumed despite their increase in price.

The over-production and overuse of fossil fuels raises environmental as well as economic concerns, since coal, petroleum, and natural gas contain high percentages of carbon; the burning of which generates greenhouse gasses (GHGs), such as Carbon Dioxide (CO2 ) contributing to the process of global warming. Although there is much argument about the extent to which the human activity contributes to climate change, the effects of climate change are undisputed, leading to increases in average temperature, altered habitats, extreme weather conditions, sea-level changes and flooding.

There are huge external costs linked to these environmental changes. As temperatures increase and rainfall patterns change, crop yields are expected to drop significantly in Africa, the Middle East and India. Water availability for irrigation and drinking will be less predictable, because rain will be more variable and droughts more frequent, creating pressure on agricultural production and diversity. Up to three billion people could suffer increased water shortages by 2080. Air and water pollution resulting from the extraction and use of fossil fuels can lead to significant health and environmental problems.

The economic consequences are significant. All businesses need resources - both raw materials and energy. As reserves of both are under strain, world prices are increasingly volatile. National and international commitments to reduce carbon emissions, are forcing governments to examining the balance of their energy production and consumption, exploring ways to reduce the use of fossil fuels if possible, to be replaced by alternative cleaner technologies. With the rapid economic growth in the emerging BRICS economies (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa), demand for raw materials and energy is outstripping supply and countries around the world are beginning to position themselves to protect their strategic interests.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

An excellent climate change glossary can be found on the BBC website.


The state of oil and natural gas production, in particular, is causing alarm. Oil production peaked during 2006 with global oil production from mature oil fields now declining at a rate of between 6-7% per year. Oil is becoming more difficult, expensive and energy intensive to extract. The Peak Oil Crisis website has real time clocks of global oil consumption and graphics illustrating the impending crisis as well as articles, graphics and links to industry articles. Countries reliant on oil imports are desperately seeking new oil and gas sources with global oil companies seeking out previously untapped reserves in the remotest of regions.

The Artic is one of the regions that likely to become an economic and realpolitik battleground, almost certainly pushing ethical, environmental and moral considerations aside in the drive to its natural resources. It has been stated by industry experts that another 5 million barrels of new oil per day must come on line per year to meet global demand. A 2008 United States Geological Survey estimated that areas north of the Arctic Circle have 90 billion barrels of undiscovered, technically recoverable oil representing 13% of the undiscovered oil in the world. In addition to the size of the untapped resources, environmental factors are driving moves to develop the Arctic region. In the past, the Northwest Passage connecting the Atlantic and Pacific Oceans through the Canadian Arctic Archipelago, has been virtually impassable, because it was covered by thick, year-round sea ice. However, satellite and other monitoring confirm a progressive, year-by-year decline in the thickness and extent of Arctic sea ice.

There is general insecurity about oil supplies in many regions. Asia, for example, only holds about 1% of the world's proven reserves of oil and gas. Oil prices are predicted to rise abruptly with apocalyptic predictions about a collapse in oil production by 2015. Asian countries, such as Japan, South Korea and India, are buying and storing crude oil in unprecedented quantities. China is planning to increase its reserves to 90 days consumption by 2020 and Singapore, preparing for the looming oil crunch, is racing to complete a series of vast man-made caverns beneath the seabed of Banyan Basin, which will include a vast oil storage complex. The first two caverns providing 480,000 cubic metres (m³) of oil storage will be constructed by 2013. Three more caves are planned, which would store enough oil to last Singapore a month.

The threat to sustainability from poverty

Population increases are both a consequence, and cause, of increasing poverty and low standards of living around the world, especially in Asia and Africa. As populations increase the demand on common access resources intensifies resulting in extensive negative externalities which threatens sustainability.

With the world's population surpassing 7 billion people in 2011, the global impact is huge.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\reflect.gif

Read the following article and reflect on the implications for sustainable development resulting from population growth.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\definition.gif

The World Bank periodically prepares poverty assessments of countries in which it has an active programme, in close collaboration with national institutions and other development agencies. The data it records is presented in a series of datasets on its website.

Examine the following datasets and featured indicators and identify the major links between poverty and reliance on agriculture.

For the 70% of the world's poor who live in rural areas, agriculture is the main source of income and employment. The depletion and degradation of natural resources poses serious challenges to producing enough food and other agricultural products to sustain local livelihoods, but also to meet the needs of urban populations which rely on this supply.

Where low-income rural populations rely on subsistence agriculture, the likelihood is that common access resources will become depleted, unless there is some form of community collaboration along the lines suggested by Elinor Ostrom. Sustainability of resources may be lost if poor communities are forced to sell land and resources, such as forests, to external private corporations who do not have the interests of the local community as a priority, but need to satisfy their shareholders. Logging companies, for example, will wish to maximise their utilisation of timber resources taking only their private costs into consideration, ignoring the external costs to the local population. As a consequence, there will be overexploitation of timber and deforestation creating negative externalities such soil erosion, landslides, flooding and loss of bio-diversity.

The World Bank is one of the key promoters and financiers of environmental upgrading in the developing world. The following dataset covers forests, biodiversity, emissions, and pollution.

Government responses to threats to sustainability

Market failure in production occurs when the production of a good or service creates external costs that are harmful to third parties, e.g. when a factory pollutes a river with waste or the atmosphere with greenhouse gasses. The total costs to society of these activities are the private costs of the firm plus the external costs that the firm creates, but does not pay for. Since the producer does not pay the total cost, the good or service is over-produced, which results in a welfare loss.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\ext_neg_prod_f.gif

National governments can respond to negative externalities of production and to resource depletion and CO2 pollution using a number of mechanisms designed to reduce emissions of global greenhouse gasses and promote sustainability. These include:

Taxation and financial penalties increase the market price of carbon. This provides strong incentives to reduce carbon emissions by sending signals:

  1. to consumers about what goods and services produce high carbon emissions and which should be used more sparingly.
  2. to producers about which inputs emit more carbon, and which emit less, so encouraging them to move to lower-carbon technologies.
  3. to inventors and innovators to develop and introduce lower-carbon products and processes.

Cap and Trade Schemes

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Cap and trade scheme

A cap and trade scheme is a market-based approach to reduce carbon emissions via financial incentives that allows corporations or national governments to trade emissions allowances under an overall cap, or limit, on those emissions. Fines are imposed for producers exceeding those limits, while producers operating below their carbon limits can sell or "trade" their offsets to companies that are operating above the limits.


Cap and trade schemes set specific limits on GHG emissions for countries and organisations. They promote the trading of emissions allowances between emitters, who can meet the cap efficiently and those who face more of a challenge in reducing emissions.

The choice between environmental taxation and cap and trade schemes to address climate change has generated considerable discussion with impassioned arguments on both sides.

Taxation has the advantage that it can be implemented by individual governments without international agreement, but, environmental taxes have dead-weight losses in addition to their beneficial effects in addressing externalities. It is also argued that establishing a price for GHGs through cap and trade schemes has the advantage of providing some certainty about reductions in quantities of emissions and creates a market to achieve the climate change mitigation target at the lowest cost.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

The following article outlines the advantages and disadvantages of cap and trade schemes compared to environmental taxes as a means of reducing emissions.

Cap and trade schemes vs. Carbon tax

You can read the article Cap and trade vs. Carbon tax in the window below, or you can follow the link to read the article in a separate window.


C:\Users\Paul\Documents\IB Business\UNITS\quotation.gif

Carbon pricing has a double climate effect - it's a huge source for revenue, but also gives the right incentives for reducing emissions by making it expensive to pollute.

Norwegian Prime Minister Jens Stoltenberg

Promoting Clean Technologies

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Clean technologies

Clean technologies are designed to minimise pollution and the emissions of greenhouse gasses, by creating electricity and fuels with a smaller environmental and carbon footprint. These technologies include recycling, renewable energies (wind and solar power, biomass and biofuels and hydropower), green transportation, waste water recycling and energy efficient lighting, homes, buildings, electric motors and commercial and domestic appliances.


The World Bank is the trustee of the Clean Technology Fund (CTF), focused on making renewable energy cost-competitive with coal-fired power. Since its launch in 2008, $US6.5 billion has been allocated to climate change projects in 45 developing countries. These payments represent a subsidy on the development and use of clean technologies.

If government or World Bank subsidies are particularly focused on the generation of electricity using renewable energy sources, such as wind and solar power, then firms generating electricity using cleaner technologies will face lower costs of production. This will encourage energy producers to produce more wind and solar power, shifting the supply curve to the right and lowering prices for consumers.

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\subsidy_electricity.gif

Subsidies or tax credits should also encourage increased investment in clean technologies. However, UN research showed 'green' investment in Europe dropped by one-fifth in 2010, while that in developing countries surge ahead.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Read the following articles and then produce a 750 word report comparing and contrasting Europe's commitment to renewable energies and cleaner technologies to that of some developing countries. Use appropriate data to support your analysis.

The 'dirty side' of cleaner technologies

Cleaner technologies are not always welcomed by local and national communities. 'Wind farms', for example, may consist of hundreds of wind turbines and are frequently criticised by some local communities for their negative environmental impacts. They are often seen as a 'blot on the landscape' as well as posing a danger for birds and bats, whose migratory and flight paths may take them into collision with wind turbines and towers.

Other alternative energy sources have created similar controversies. The production of biofuels has resulted in food price inflation worldwide, with land previously used for growing food for human consumption being transferred to the production of crops used to produce biofuels.

A 2011 report from the Nuffield Council on the Bioethics examined the ethical issues of biofuels and the serious negative impacts on the livelihoods of some of those who cultivate the land, on the sustainability of cultivation systems and on biodiversity.

The following videos discuss the role of science in addressing some of the problems associated with finding, and commercialising, alternatives to fossil fuels:


C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Improving alternative energy sources




\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\reflect.gif

Why are subsidies for alternative energies still lagging behind those for nuclear oil or coal?

International responses to threats to sustainability

Government responses to threats to sustainability are limited by the global nature of the problems and the lack of ownership of common access resources. Therefore, effective responses require international cooperation.

The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC or FCCC)

The UNFCCC is an international environmental treaty resulting from the 1992 United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (the 'Earth Summit'), held in Rio de Janeiro. The objective of the treaty was to stabilise greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere, although it was considered legally non-binding as it set no mandatory limits on greenhouse gas emissions for individual countries. However, the treaty provided for future 'protocols' or updates that would set these enforceable limits.

The 1997 Kyoto Protocol

The Kyoto Protocol established legally binding obligations for developed countries to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions. Industrialised countries agreed to reduce their combined emissions to 5.2% below 1990 levels during the five-year period 2008-2012. The protocol came into force in 2005.

Parties to the UNFCCC are classified as:

Under the Kyoto Protocol, Annex I countries must limit their emissions, while non-Annex I countries have a variety of non-binding commitments.

However, it is commonly agreed that developed countries cannot reduce carbon emission enough to stabilise GHG concentrations to a level where the risk of global temperature exceeding 2 degrees centigrade is minimised, without the participation of developing countries, especially China and India. Developing countries may volunteer to become Annex I countries when they are sufficiently developed.

A 2010 World Bank report says a climate smart world is achievable for developing countries, but only with financial and technical support from the developed world. The World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change also says high income countries must lead global action on climate change by reducing their own heavy carbon footprints.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\vodcast.gif


Asymmetric information

For markets to function perfectly, all parties to an economic transaction should have perfect knowledge about the terms of the contract, the products and services that form the subject of the agreement and the prices in the market. In practice, the real commercial world rarely confirms to this ideal, and it is common for one of the parties to have better and/or more knowledge than the other, leading to imperfect competition and market failure. This situation is called asymmetric or imperfect information.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Asymmetric information

Asymmetric information or imperfect information, occurs where access to information by one party (or parties) to an economic transaction is better than access by another party.


Properly functioning markets provide a valuable service to society, because consumers are able to purchase the goods and services that best match their preferences. However, asymmetric information can be used as a source of power in determining the outcome of the transaction. As a consequence, the market will not achieve allocative efficiency, because one of the parties - in this case normally the consumer, pays a higher price for a product than they would have done if they had perfect knowledge. In a perfect market, consumer and producer surplus should both be maximised at the market price, i.e. the conditions are in place for a Pareto optimum allocation of resources.

A common example of where the buyer pays more for a good than is socially efficient is where the seller knows much more about the characteristics of that good than the buyer. For example where:

It is also possible that the consumer has more information than the seller. For example, purchasers with specialist knowledge of antiques may be able to buy a antique for a price less than its true market value from a private seller, who does not have this expert knowledge.

The government has a number of policy tools at its disposal to correct asymmetric information and to control externalities. These include taxes, education programmes and production regulation intended to increase the flow of information to consumers. Government may decide to intervene in the market to require producers to disclose critical information, such as mandatory product labelling. The objective of this government intervention may not be to alter consumption behaviour in particular, but to increase informed consumption. However, these measures can be expensive and ineffective and perceived as government interference in the free market.

The growth of computer ownership with access to the internet has reduced the opportunities for asymmetric information, as consumers are able to access greater details on products, prices and customer reviews.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\group_activity.gif

Read the following article and discuss whether the marketing and sale of Sunny Delight in 2003 was an example of asymmetric information in practice.

Abuse of monopoly power

monopoly02A most important assumption of the ideal free market economy is that markets within it are competitive, so that a large number of competing firms passively take the price that is set in the market as a whole and either increase or decrease their output in response to shifts in consumer demand.

However, as we saw in the section on monopoly, markets may be dominated by a single producer of the good or service, in which case a situation of monopoly exists, or by a few producers, in which case an oligopoly exists. In either situation, producers may not be content to take a price set in the market. Having significant control over supply, firms in pursuit of maximum profits may attempt to make the market price higher than it would otherwise have been by restricting output. The outcome for consumers may therefore be that they are paying a higher price for a smaller output. This would represent market failure and a misallocation of society's scarce resources, as the economy would be deprived of some of the output which would be valued more highly than that currently being consumed.

Also, in a situation of monopoly or oligopoly, profits may not perform the function that they are supposed to in the 'ideal' free market situation. Here, the making of profit is deemed to be a sign of efficiency; that is, the goods that are being produced are precisely those that consumers want and of a suitably high quality, and because firms cannot influence price, the profit has been achieved by operating efficiently, with costs being kept below the ruling price. However, given the power of firms in monopoly and oligopoly to restrict output to keep price artificially high, the making of profits may reflect market power and dominance rather than efficiency. Monopoly may involve both allocative and technical inefficiency. Refer back to the section on monopoly and re-read the course notes if you are not sure about this.

Inequality

Advocates of a freely operating price system often liken it to a political democracy where all voters can cast their votes for the candidates of their choice, with everyone who is eligible having an equal say: the price system, according to this line of reasoning, is a consumers', economic democracy; every time we go out and buy a particular good, we are affecting the demand for that good, and hence also its profitability and supply. Hence, the simple act of buying a good is akin to casting a 'vote' in favour of the production of that good, and is the way in which consumers determine how scarce resources should be allocated.

Unlike the political democracy however, in which each person has equal voting rights, the consumer democracy described above, given the unequal distribution of income that exists in most capitalist economies, is unlikely to be one in which all have an equal say _ clearly voting power is directly related to income so that the rich would have many more votes, and thus a much greater pull on resources, than the poor. Consequently, the resulting pattern of resource allocation may overlook the pressing, often life and death needs of the poor, and reflect instead the more trivial wants of the rich. In the economics of the market place, human wants are those that are supported by effective demand i.e. demand backed by the ability and willingness to pay the market price. Human needs, however, if unaccompanied by the wherewithal to pay, are simply ignored. This is the overriding reason for the existence of mal-nutrition and starvation in the world today: it is not that there is an overall shortage of food - there is more than enough in total terms to feed everyone; the problem, quite simply, is that those who need the food lack the money to pay for it.

Hence the 'free' market, given the degree of inequality which typically exists, is likely to be one in which many people are severely disadvantaged in terms of their market power. 'Electoral successes' will be the fast cars, exquisite jewellery and luxury hotels etc. for those who can pay, with basic health care, education, safe drinking water and nutritious food for the poor almost certainly 'losing their deposits'. Clearly, some consumers are a lot more 'sovereign' than others!

Section 1.4 Market failure - questions

In this section are a series of questions on the topic - market failure. The questions may include various types of questions. For example:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to work through the questions.

Market failure - short answer

question

Market failure - introduction

Question 1

Explain the term market failure.

Question 2

What is short-termism, and what is its role in market failure?

Question 3

(a) Explain why environmental pollution is regarded as a source of market failure.

(b) Evaluate two different policies that a government might implement to reduce pollution.

Question 4

Assess the arguments for and against subsidising public transport.

Question 5

Friedman

"The existence of a free market does not of course eliminate the need for government. On the contrary, government is essential both as a forum for determining the rules of the game and as an umpire to enforce the rules decided on.

What the market does is to reduce greatly the range of issues that must be decided through political means, and thereby to minimise the extent to which government need participate directly in the game. The characteristic feature of action through political channels is that it tends to require or enforce substantial conformity. The great advantage of the market, on the other hand, is that it permits wide diversity. It is, in political terms, a system of proportional representation. Each man can vote, as it were, for the colour of tie he wants and get it: he does not have to see what colour the majority wants and then, if he is in the minority, submit."

Source: Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago University Press, 1962)

Thatcher

"Freedom is indivisible. Once the state controls the means of production, distribution and exchange, all of us would become dependent on it." (1986)

Gray

"Hayek's insight is that against a background of stable laws, human individuals, left to their own devices, will produce an order spontaneously which is more complex and more stable than any which could be designed by the human mind. It's also an order ... which embodies their purposes and their goals. The moral defence of the market is that it protects freedom and voluntary exchange: whereas the moral hazard of economic planning is that it subordinates the purposes of some to those of the rulers."

John Gray (Oxford University, 1989)

Part (a)

All three quotes equate "freedom" with a market system. Explain the reasons that the authors would be likely to give for this.

Part (b)

In what ways might a market system not lead to greater "freedom" for all?

Externalities - short answer

question

Positive and negative externalities

Question 1

Distinguish between private costs and social costs using examples to illustrate your answers.

Question 2

Explain the difference between (i) a social cost and a negative externality and (ii) a social benefit and a positive externality.

Question 3

Re-write and fill in the gaps in the text below:

The existence of negative externalities will lead to a misallocation of resources and over-production at the free market price. The existence of positive externalities will cause a misallocation of resources at the free market price as there will be .........................................................................

Negative externalities cause a divergence between private and social cost.

The private cost is the internal money cost of production incurred by the firm i.e. costs such as ................................................................... Which must be paid to carry out production, and which would appear in the firm's accounts.

The social cost, on the other hand, is the real cost to society; it is the private internal costs plus ....................................

Similarly, if the firm's production decisions were to generate positive externalities, such as the beneficial effects arising from the provision of employment, then there would be a divergence between private and social benefit.

The private benefit is the money value of the benefits accruing internally to the firm from production activity e.g. in the form of sales revenues.

The social benefit, on the other hand, is the private benefit plus ..............................

So, social cost = ...................... + ...................... and social benefit = ...................... + ......................

The difference between the private and social cost is therefore the value of the ...................... and the difference between the private and social benefit is therefore the value of ......................

Externalities & allocative efficiency - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain in your own words how traffic congestion leads to allocative inefficiency.

Externalities - self-test questions

question

1

Externalities

What type of externality is evident from the picture below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This pollution is a production externality. No, that's not right. This pollution is a production externality.Yes, that's correct. This pollution is an external cost as the cost is borne by people other than the factory polluting. This means that pollution is a negative production externality.No, that's not right. A positive production externality would be something that has an external benefit. Pollution is an external cost and so is a negative externality.
Check your answer

2

Externalities

What type of externality is evident from the picture below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. A negative consumption externality would be one that led to external costs. This attractive sculpture in someone's garden will have external benefits as other can also enjoy it. Yes, that's correct. This attractive sculpture in someone's garden will have external benefits as other can also enjoy it.No, that's not right. Someone has bought this sculpture and hung it in their garden which allows others to enjoy it. It therefore offers external benefits arising from consumption.No, that's not right. Someone has bought this sculpture and hung it in their garden which allows others to enjoy it. It therefore offers external benefits arising from consumption.
Check your answer

3

Externalities

What type of externality is evident from the picture below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct. A negative consumption externality is one that leads to external costs. Smoking is a consumption activity and results in costs being imposed on those other than just the people smoking (health costs etc). It is therefore a negative consumption externality.No, that's not right. A positive consumption externality is one that leads to external benefits. Smoking is a consumption activity that results in external costs (health costs etc).No, that's not right. Smoking is a consumption activity and so is a consumption externality.No, that's not right. Smoking is a consumption activity and so is a consumption externality.
Check your answer

4

Externalities

What type of externality is evident from the picture below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answer No, that's not right. A negative consumption externality is one that leads to external costs. The external costs here are arising from a production activity (production and storage of gas).No, that's not right. A positive consumption externality is one that leads to external benefits. This image shows external costs arising from a production activity (production and storage of gas).Yes, that's correct. The gasholder leads to an external cost for this house (and people passing by) and arises from a production activity.No, that's not right. The gasholder leads to an external cost for this house (and people passing by) and arises from a production activity.
Check your answer

5

Externalities

What type of externality is evident from the picture below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct. A negative consumption externality is one that leads to external costs. The external costs here are arising from the consumption activity of buying and using cars for transport.No, that's not right. This is a consumption externality, but a positive consumption externality is one that leads to external benefits. This image shows external costs arising from the dumping of a car.No, that's not right. Though there may have negative consumption externalities arising from the production of the car in the first place, these external costs have arisen from the consumption and dumping of a car.No, that's not right. The image shows external costs arising from consumption of a car and the car subsequently being dumped.
Check your answer

6

Externalities

The image below shows syringes used for vaccination. What type of externality is evident from this?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answer No, that's not right. A negative consumption externality is one that leads to external costs. Vaccination will lead to external benefits rather than costs. Yes, that's correct. Vaccination will lead to external benefits as it will protect other from catching diseases.No, that's not right. Vaccination is a consumption activity and so any externalities resulting from it will be consumption externalities.No, that's not right. Vaccination is a consumption activity and so any externalities resulting from it will be consumption externalities.
Check your answer

Public goods - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain, with the aid of examples, the main characteristics of public goods.

Question 2

To what extent is it desirable that the government should provide public goods?

Question 3

Identify goods that are non-pure public goods, and explain in each case why some excludability and diminishability are possible.

Question 4

Why are health and education not pure public goods?

Question 5

Classify the following goods as either public (P), merit (M) or demerit goods.

Good Public (P), merit (M) or demerit (D)?
Dentistry
Museums
Birth control
Radio transmissions
Marijuana
Sea defences
Seat belts
Public parks
Nursery education (pre-school)
Loft insulation
Theatres
Lighthouses
Motorways
Cocaine
Vaccinations
Milk
Cigarettes
Alcohol


Merit goods - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain, with the aid of examples, the main characteristics of merit goods.

Question 2

To what extent is it desirable that the government should provide merit goods?

Question 3

Discuss the case for and against doctors charging patients for their services

Question 4

Why might housing be described as a merit good?

Question 5

Discuss the arguments for and against the state reducing its role in the direct provision of housing.

Question 6

Classify the following goods as either public (P), merit (M) or demerit goods.

Good Public (P), merit (M) or demerit (D)?
Health care (free)
Museums
Birth control
Radio transmissions
Marijuana
Sea defences
Seat belts
Public parks
Nursery education (pre-school)
Theatres
Lighthouses
Motorways
Cocaine
Vaccinations
Milk
Cigarettes
Alcohol


Question 7

The effect of subsidising theatre tickets will, to a large extent, depend on the elasticity of demand for theatre tickets. Draw two diagrams, one with a relatively inelastic demand curve and one with a relatively elastic demand curve. Explain the different effects on price and quantity.

Question 8

"Education, health care and housing are best provided through the market." Discuss.

Demerit goods - short answer

question

Question 1

Discuss the possible economic arguments for and against the legalisation of cannabis in a country where it is currently illegal.

Question 2

Evaluate the introduction of a government policy to ban smoking in all work places and public places.

Types of goods - self-test questions

question

1

Types of goods

How would you classify the type of good shown in the image below?

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\Centurion_Tank.jpg

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answer Yes, that's correct. Well done. Defence is considered to be non-rival and non-excludable and is therefore a public good.No, that's not right. Merit goods are goods which are deemed to be socially desirable, and which are likely to be under-produced and under-consumed through the market mechanism. Defence would not be provided at all through the market mechanism and is therefore a public good. No, that's not right. A demerit good is a good which is deemed to be socially undesirable, and which are likely to be over-produced and over-consumed through the market mechanism.No, that's not right. Free goods are goods which we can consume in infinite quantities without any cost. They take no resources to produce and can be obtained without having to give up the opportunity to produce another good.
Check your answer

2

Types of goods

How would you classify the type of good shown in the image below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Smoking is not non-rival and non-excludable in consumption and is therefore not a public good.No, that's not right. Merit goods are goods which are deemed to be socially desirable, and which are likely to be under-produced and under-consumed through the market mechanism. Smoking would be over-provided through the market mechanism and is therefore a demerit good.Yes, that's correct. Well done. A demerit good is a good which is deemed to be socially undesirable, and which are likely to be over-produced and over-consumed through the market mechanism. Smoking is a good of this nature.No, that's not right. Free goods are goods which we can consume in infinite quantities without any cost. They take no resources to produce and can be obtained without having to give up the opportunity to produce another good.
Check your answer

3

Types of goods

How would you classify the type of good represented by the image below?

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\stethoscope.jpg

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Health care is not entirely non-rival and non-excludable in consumption and is therefore not a public good. It has social benefits when provided and is therefore usually categorised as a merit good. Yes, that's correct. Well done. Merit goods are goods which are deemed to be socially desirable, and which are likely to be under-produced and under-consumed through the market mechanism. This is the case with healthcare and it is therefore usually categorised as a merit good. No, that's not right. A demerit good is a good which is deemed to be socially undesirable, and which are likely to be over-produced and over-consumed through the market mechanism. Healthcare is the opposite of this and is therefore a merit good.No, that's not right. Free goods are goods which we can consume in infinite quantities without any cost. They take no resources to produce and can be obtained without having to give up the opportunity to produce another good. Healthcare takes significant resources to provide.
Check your answer

4

Types of goods

How would you classify the type of good shown in the image below?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answer Yes, that's correct. Well done. A lighthouse is considered to be non-rival and non-excludable and is therefore a public good.No, that's not right. Merit goods are goods which are deemed to be socially desirable, and which are likely to be under-produced and under-consumed through the market mechanism. Lighthouses would not be provided at all through the market mechanism (too difficult to 'exclude' people who haven't paid) and are therefore a public good. No, that's not right. A demerit good is a good which is deemed to be socially undesirable, and which are likely to be over-produced and over-consumed through the market mechanism.No, that's not right. Free goods are goods which we can consume in infinite quantities without any cost. They take no resources to produce and can be obtained without having to give up the opportunity to produce another good.
Check your answer

Government responses - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain the functions that prices perform in a market economy

Question 2

Assess the case for and against using the price mechanism to relieve the problem of traffic congestion.

Question 3

Discuss the importance of the distinction between private costs and social costs for a government considering whether or not to help finance the construction of a new railway line.

Question 4

What remedies could the government take to remedy the allocative inefficiency arising from traffic congestion?

Common access resources - activities

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

Read the article A solution can never manifest itself if it comes at the cost of other party and answer the following questions.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\question.gif

Question 1

Define the term 'common pool resources'

Question 2

Outline two reasons why the fishing resources in the Palk Straits and the Gulf of Mannaw can be described as a common pool resource.

Question 3

Explain, how the governments of Sri Lanka and India are limited in their responses to the threat to sustainability of their fishing stocks, by the global nature of the fishing resources.

Question 4

Using diagrams and information from the article and your knowledge of economics, evaluate the extent to which the government of Sri Lanka can address the issue of conservation and management of its fish stocks through cooperation with the Indian government.

Overexploitation - questions

Overexploitation occurs when a water resource, such as the Ogallala Aquifer, is extracted at a higher rate than is sustainable.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

Read the article Governor Brownback and the Ogallala Aquifer in Kansas and consider the following questions:


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\question.gif

Question 1

Explain why the Ogallala Aquifer is considered an 'engine of economic growth'

Question 2

Explain why the Ogallala Aquifer is prone to exploitation and over-consumption and why policy changes aimed toward sustainability require collective action.

Question 3

Outline the policy solutions available to protect degradation of water resources in Kansas and discuss to what extent these are easier to implement than the policies designed to conserve and manage fishing stocks in Sri Lanka.

Sustainability - report

PwC is one of the world's largest providers of assurance, tax, and business consulting services.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\read.gif

Read extracts from the Pwc climate change and sustainability blog on 2010 United Nations Climate Change Conference held in Cancún, Mexico.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Produce a 500 -750 word article for an environmental journal on the purpose and scope of the Cancún conference, and its achievements, compromises and disappointments.

You may wish to read this Wikipedia article and conduct additional Internet research to provide the background for your article, possibly using the footnotes to the Wikipedia article to find the original sources.

Plastic bags - carrying the weight of the environment?

Read the article Plastic bag bans around the world and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also wish to read the following article to support your answer:

podcast

Once you have read this article then listen to the following podcast:


question

Question 1

Identify the external costs and external benefits that result from the use of single-use plastic bags.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, show how the use of single-use plastic bags results in the socially optimal equilibrium differing from the market equilibrium.

Question 3

Analyse the effectiveness of banning the use of plastic bags as a policy to reduce the environmental impact of carrying goods from shops.

Question 4

Evaluate two policies, other than bans, that governments could use to reduce the environmental impact of the use of plastic bags.

Running cars on biofuels can be unethical

Read the article Running cars on biofuels can be unethical and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may wish to read the following articles to help you answer the questions:


question

Question 1

Identify the external costs and external benefits that result from the use of biofuels as a partial source of fuel for drivers in the developed world.

Question 2

Analyse the impact on the market for petrol of the increased use of biofuels.

Question 3

With reference to the article, discuss whether the growing use of biofuels increases or reduces the external costs of driving in the developed world.

Question 4

Discuss the extent to which governments in the developed world need to adopt policies to reduce demand for driving as opposed to introducing biofuels to reduce the overall environmental impact.

Cement - the hidden polluter?

Read the article The unheralded polluter: cement industry comes clean on its impact and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

With reference to the article, identify the main external costs resulting from the production of cement.

Question 3

Analyse the extent to which there is a "trade-off between development and sustainability" as identified by Dimitri Paplexopoulos, managing director of Titan Cement.

Question 4

Discuss policies that governments could adopt to try to move the market for cement to a more socially optimal equilibrium.

African roses - a sign of change

Read the article Flowers are sign of economic change in Ethiopia and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also like to read the following article relating to African flowers:


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Draw a diagram to show the social optimum in the market for roses.

Question 3

Compare and contrast the social costs and social benefits (including both private and external costs) of buying roses produced in Europe and those produced in Africa.

Congestion charging

Read the article Leafy Kensington shows its anger and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Identify two external costs resulting from traffic congestion in London.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, explain the impact of the extended congestion zone on traffic levels in London.

Question 3

Discuss whether the implementation of a larger congestion zone will help move closer to a socially optimal position in this market.

Question 4

Choose one other measure that the Mayor of London could introduce to meet emissions targets for the city and evaluate its likely success.

Putting a price on carbon

Read the article China plans carbon trading pilot scheme and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also like to read the following articles relating to carbon trading schemes:


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Explain how the use of cap and trade schemes is intended to reduce emissions of CO2.

Question 3

Explain the scope and objectives of the Kyoto Protocol.

Question 4

Discuss the relative merits of using carbon taxation as a policy to help meet emissions targets in comparison to cap and trade schemes.

Question 5

According to the Stern Review ".... the second ingredient necessary to tackle climate change [i]s a range of policies to support the development of low-carbon and high-efficiency technologies." Identify two policies that would help achieve this and evaluate their likely success.


Extension activity:

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Reducing Carbon emissions

Investigate the success of recent schemes and agreements to reduce carbon emissions. Prepare a 500 - 1000 word report on your findings, including some of the following:

Power bills to soar in 'green reforms'

Read the articles Power bills to soar by 30% in 'green' reforms and Three solutions in one to a string of problems the free market could not deal with then answer the questions below. You can either read the articles in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the articles in a separate window.



question

Question 1

Define the following terms:

Question 2

Explain the operations of the electricity market reforms (EMR).

Question 3

Analyse the costs and benefits of the proposed electricity market reforms.

Question 4

Discuss the view that government needs to regulate the energy, because the free market cannot address the issue of energy shortages without creating unacceptable negative externalities.


Extension Activity:

\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\reflect.gif

European Green Capital 2010

What lessons can be learned from Stockholm's approach to their urban environment and in particular their urban policies on traffic congestion, waste management, pollution and the emission of greenhouse gasses? Could these be applied in the areas where you live?


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Identify and explain 5 key environmental approaches used in Stockholm that could be applied to other global cities.

Beyond Kyoto

Kyoto is the only international agreement with binding targets for curbing greenhouse gas emissions, but China and the United States, the world's biggest polluters, are not subject to its constraints. Under Kyoto, developed countries are allowed to establish domestic and internationally linked emissions trading schemes and purchase emissions reductions in developing countries and count them as their own. But on December 31 2012, Kyoto will expire without a successor agreement.

Since the 2007 Bali summit countries have been in a negotiating deadlock over different paths for a post-Kyoto agreement. Developing countries want a second Kyoto emissions reduction period because it puts the entire onus on developed countries.

Non-European developed countries want a new non-binding agreement that brings all the leading emitters into the tent. European countries want a mix of both. The failure to agree over what was being negotiated, let alone the detail, led to the eruption at the 2009 Copenhagen summit.

The absence of a global framework undermines the political and policy case for prioritising emissions cuts. Any knowledge of international relations - or human nature - should tell us that a non-binding treaty on climate change is about as effective as a peace vigil in a bombing raid. Staying with a non-binding treaty model means we are all unhappy and the planet is doomed. Good diplomacy is, as always, about taking what you can get.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gifS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\reflect.gif

You have been asked by a student run economics website to write a blog post on the theme of climate change. The editor has asked that the post summarises the recent history of international summits on climate change and then comments on the possibility of reaching a further international agreement on emissions following the expiry of the Kyoto agreement. You have decided to entitle your post 'Beyond Kyoto'.

Use the following links as a starting point for your research:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

read

You may also like to read the following articles relating to climate change:

Economic growth cannot continue

Read the article Economic growth 'cannot continue' and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


questionQuestion 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Examine the economic costs that are likely to result from climate change.

Question 3

Choose one policy that a government could adopt to reduce climate change and evaluate its likely success.

Question 4

To what extent can the following views of the NEF and the Adam Smith Institute be reconciled?

We urgently need to change our economy to live within its environmental budget. A new macroeconomic model is needed, that allows the human population as a whole to thrive without having to relying on ultimately impossible, endless increases in consumption.

National Economic Foundation. (NEF)

It is precisely economic growth which will lift the poor out of poverty and improve the environmental standards that really matter to people - like clean air and water - in the process, as it has done throughout human history. There's only one good thing I can say for the Nef's report, and that's that it is honest. Its authors admit that they want us to be poorer and to lead more restricted lives for the sake of their faddish beliefs.

Adam Smith Institute

The rush to find Jade

Read the article China's new jade rush as prices soar and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Identify two external costs and two external benefits that may result from the 'jade rush' taking place on the Kashgar River

Question 2

Identify the factors that have caused the price of Hotan Jade to increase so dramatically.

Question 3

Using diagrams, as appropriate, show the socially optimal level of jade output and price.

Question 4

Evaluate possible policies that the Chinese authorities could adopt to minimise the external impact of prospecting for jade on the Kashgar River.

Chopstick tax

Read the article Chopsticks: The cutlery conundrum and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Identify and explain the external costs and external benefits resulting from the use of disposable wooden chopsticks in China.

Question 2

Discuss the likely effectiveness of the 5% chopsticks tax on reducing the demand for chopsticks. You should consider the likely value of the price elasticity of demand in your answer.

Question 3

With the use of appropriate diagrams, assess the likely impact of the chopsticks tax on the equilibrium level of price and output in the market for disposable chopsticks.

Taxing light bulbs - that's a bright idea

Read the article Bright idea and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


read

You may also like to read the following article:

question

Question 1

Explain, with reference to external costs and external benefits, why campaigners argue for a tax on incandescent light bulbs.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, show the impact of a tax on incandescent light bulbs on (a) the market for incandescent light bulbs and (b) the market for energy efficient bulbs.

Question 3

Evaluate two further policies that governments could adopt to reduce carbon emissions resulting from energy use.

Trading pig excrement

Trading pig excrement - a particularly smelly form of market failure

Pig meat accounts for nearly 40% of global meat consumption. Pigs emit methane from their nether regions (excrement) and these are a contributory factor to global warming. Under EU rules for emissions, this increases farmer's costs. So what's the solution? Well agricultural firms can capture the methane and then use it as a bio-fuel rather than allowing it to be emitted into the atmosphere. Farmer's will then be able to claim carbon credits under EU emissions trading market.

No, this really isn't an April Fool! Read the following articles: Pig manure means big bucks and Where there's muck, there's brass and answer the questions below. You can read these in the windows below, or follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window. Then answer the questions below questions below.



read

You may also like to read the following articles relating to recycling methane from pigs:


question

Question 1

Explain why methane emissions are considered a form of market failure.

Question 2

Using diagrams, as appropriate, show how methane emissions from pig waste may result in a misallocation of resources.

Question 3

Using the diagrams from question 2, show the impact of using technology to collect the methane from pigs and sell it or use it to gain carbon credits.

Question 4

Examine how the EU carbon emissions trading system help to reduce emissions of greenhouse gases.

Question 5

Evaluate two policies that the government could implement to encourage the use of alternative fuels like the new pig fat bio-diesel.

Congestion pricing

Urban road transportation creates several externalities, the most important of which are congestion (time delay and extra fuel consumption), accidents, pollution, and greenhouse gas emissions. Road pricing is widely promoted as a tool to reduce these externalities.

Read the article In London, a charge to drive eases up the roads and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


readS:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\vodcast.gif

You may also like to read the following articles and watch the embedded video relating to congestion pricing:


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Explain the reasons for charging drivers for the use of roads.

Question 3

In the light of the report quoted in the article, discuss the likely success of road charging as a policy to reduce congestion on the roads.

Question 4

Evaluate two further policies that a government could use to reduce the level of traffic congestion.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Extension activity: New York Congestion Pricing

New York congestion pricing was proposed in 2006 by New York City Mayor Michael Bloomberg's for vehicles travelling into, or within, the Manhattan central business district. The congestion pricing charge was one component of PlaNYC 2030; a policy to improve the city's future environmental sustainability, while planning for population growth.

However, the opposition to the scheme was so overwhelming, that the proposal was never put to a vote.

Using the web links and video below, write a 500 - 1000 word report:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

Congestion Pricing


read

You may also like to read the following articles relating to New York's proposed congestion charge:

Packaging tax

Read the article A tax on packaging would hurt Irish business and hit the poor and then answer the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Explain why Ireland is proposing a tax on packaging waste.

Question 2

Discuss the likely effectiveness of this tax in increasing the level of packaging waste.

Question 3

Suggest two further strategies for the government to adopt to increase the level of recycling and evaluate the likely success of one of these.


\\10.10.9.2\file server\TripleA\Design\icons\small\find_out.gif

Check your sources...

Note that the article, 'A tax on packaging would hurt Irish business and hit the poor', represents the views of the packaging industry. Can you find 'other voices' which support taxation on packaging in Ireland and/or other countries?

Airport expansion plans

Read the article To Expand, Airports May Need Radical Alterations, Report Says and then answer the questions below.


C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\vodcast.gif

read

You may also like to read the following additional articles and watch the associated video to support your answers:


question

Question 1

Define the terms:

Question 2

Explain how aeroplane flights may create either a negative externality of consumption or a negative externality of production.

Question 3

With the use of diagrams evaluate the arguments for and against the expansion of Kennedy airport.

Section 1.4 Market failure - simulations and activities

In this section are a series of simulations and activities on the topic - market failure. These simulations and activities might include:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to move on to the next page.

Step-by-step - negative consumption externalities

In this section we look at step by step versions of the externalities diagrams. It is worth going through these to see how the different externalities affect the market.


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - positive consumption externalities


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - negative production externalities


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - positive production externalities


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

1.5 Theory of the firm

In the previous sections we explained markets, the rules of supply and demand, market equilibrium, the price mechanism and market efficiency and how demand and supply are used to calculate market price and plot market equilibrium. We then explained the concepts of elasticity, considered the role and effects of government intervention in the economy and examined the concept of market failure. In this section we examine the theory of the firm.

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

1.5 Theory of the firm - notes (HL only)

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\HL.gif

gherkin02In this section of the module, we start to look at the basis of supply. We know that consumers create demand and that firms create supply, but we need to look at the behaviour of firms in more detail if we are to understand supply fully.

The first stage of this is to look at the costs of production. This may seem an odd place to start, but costs are fundamental to supply. Firms exist to make a profit - that is their key objective. If their costs rise, then they will be more reluctant to supply and so we need to understand the costs they face.

In this section we consider the following topics in detail:

Cost theory


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:



If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Calculating costs

You also need to be able to calculate a firm's costs from given data, be able to draw cost curves and then interpret what they mean. We come to that skill later.

You will also need to identify and explain short-run and long-run cost curves. Look carefully at the following examples.

ac1

Figure 3 Short-run average cost curve

lrac1

Figure 4 Long-run average cost curve

In the short-run, at least one factor input is fixed. In the long-run all inputs are variable. This means that short-run curves are models of what is happening. Long-run curves are planning data. A firm cannot operate with all inputs variable. Having decided what it wants from an examination of the long-run curves, the firm makes a decision to fix a factor, usually capital, and this gives rise to a new short-run situation.

Now, the calculations and the drawing!

You could be presented with data in the form of a table, like the one below

Output (units 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Total cost ($k) 100 110 125 145 170 200 235 275 320 370 425


Plot this with output on the horizontal axis and total cost on the vertical axis and look at it.

There is also a static version of this graph available.

What do you know now?

question

Now, some more sums. Work out the average cost (TC / output), the total variable cost (TC - FC), the variable cost (TVC / output), the average fixed cost (FC / Output) and the marginal cost (TC (Qx) - TC (Qx-1)).

Once you have had a go at calculating all these, follow the answer link below to compare how you got on.

Answer - cost calculations

Now plot this data on two separate graphs as follows, and see what it shows.

Graph 1 - Total cost, total variable costs and total fixed costs
Graph 2 - Marginal cost, average cost, average fixed cost and average variable cost

You should get the following:

Graph 1 Total cost, total variable costs and total fixed costs

There is also a static version of this graph available.

Graph 2 - Marginal cost, average cost, average fixed cost and average variable cost

There is also a static version of this graph available.

See Figure 6 below for the standard representation of these curves.

Why do average and marginal cost cross at the minimum point of average cost?

Well think of this in terms of cricket scores. Your last innings is your 'marginal' innings, whereas your batting average is your 'average'. Say your average is 50 and in your next innings you get 20 runs. What happens to your average? It will fall. However, if in your next innings you get 80 runs. In this case your average will rise.

So, if the marginal is below the average, the average will fall and if the marginal is above the average, the average will rise.

There are many questions for you to work on in the questions section (click on the questions - module 2 link in the left hand navigation bar). It may also be worth having a look at the Diggin' diagrams sections (accessible from the course homepage) to check how well you understand your diagrams.

Summary

Remember, a standard marginal and average cost curve diagram should look like this:

mc_ac

Figure 5 Marginal and average cost

Add in the average fixed and average variable cost curves and it should look like this:

mc_ac_avc_afc

Figure 6 Marginal cost, average cost, average fixed cost and average variable cost

Short-run

It is important to know the difference between the short run and the long run. The law of diminishing returns is a short run law. Economies and diseconomies of scale occur in the long run.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Short run

The short run is the period of time in which at least one factor of production is fixed. Over this time period the firm can only expand production by using more of the variable factor.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Long run

The long run is the period of time when all factor inputs, including capital, can be changed.


You need to remember these as the time period makes a big difference to how the firm can react to changes in circumstances. In the short-run their capacity is fixed and so all they can do is employ more variable factors. They cannot expand the scale or size of the firm. In the long-run though they can. We put the word scale in bold just now because it is important - economies of scale will only arise in the long-run. In the short-run we get diminishing returns to a factor (because the firm can only change the variable factor).


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

This theory supports the shape of the marginal and average cost curves. Both of these curves will be u-shaped as eventually diminishing returns will lead to costs increasing. Initially increasing returns mean that both AC and MC will fall, but once diminishing returns set in both curves start to rise again. The MC and AC curves are shown in Figures 2 and 3, although we will return to these in more detail in the next section.

mc

Figure 2 Marginal cost curve

ac

Figure 3 Average cost curve

The marginal cost curve will intersect the average cost curve at its minimum point.

The actual position of the AC curve will vary with a number of factors.

Productivity is measured in a number of ways:

The choice of factor inputs will be driven by their costs, productivity and effect on product cost. An efficient firm will make its choices so as to minimise its average cost at the production rate being worked. Look at the following example.

eg

Example

Student Computers make DVD drives. Its average cost curve is shown in figure 4 below.

ac_ex1

Figure 4 Average cost curve for Student Computers on 1st May 2002

The following then takes place:

Business rates increase (fixed costs (FC))
Insurance premiums rise (FC)
Wage rates (variable costs (VC)) and salaries (FC) increase

This will change the cost curves. The curve will move upwards due to the increase in fixed costs. The average cost of production at the present output will rise from C1 to C2. Unless something is done about it, the profits will fall.

ac_ex2

Figure 5 Average cost curves for Student Computers on date 1

In response to these changes the research and development department introduces new materials that are cheaper to buy than the old ones. They also introduce new working practices and procedures that increase productivity considerably. The savings are shared between the firm and its employees. This all reduces variable costs and the AC curve falls again. Now the production average cost, at C3, is lower than before.

ac_ex3

Figure 6 Average cost curves for Student Computers on date 2

The firm has responded to rises in certain costs by taking steps to reduce others.

Long-run

First let's remind ourselves of the definitions and what type of economies of scale there are. It is important to remember that economies/diseconomies of scale occur in the long run, with all factors variable.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Economies of scale

Economies of scale are the advantages that an organisation gains due to an increase in size. These will lead to a decrease in the average costs of production.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Diseconomies of scale

Diseconomies of scale are the disadvantages that an organisation experiences due to an increase in size. They will increase the average costs per unit.



If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Internal economies of scale


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

External economies of scale


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Diseconomies of scale


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Long run cost curves

The long run cost curve of a firm is sometimes called an 'envelope' curve as it envelopes all the short run average cost curves. Consider the different ways that capital intensive and labour intensive industries develop. First, some definitions:

Capital-intensive activities have long, deep long-run average cost curves. Small firms cannot compete against large ones; the difference in average cost is too great. A few large firms, with perhaps a few small but very specialist businesses, will dominate industries. Examples here would include the petro-chemical industries. Look at Figure 2.

lrac2

Figure 2 Long-run AC curve for capital-intensive business

Labour intensive activities have short and relatively flat long-run average cost curves. There is little advantage in being large, so the industry develops with many small firms. Examples would include the fishing industry in Asian countries where the industry comprises many family-run firms using basic fishing equipment and small boats. Look at Figure 3.

lrac3

Figure 3 Long-run AC curve for labour intensive business

This means that it is very expensive to try to enter a capital-intensive industry. The minimum scale of operation will be high and will require a large investment of capital. The risk will be high, and the capital will be hard to raise. The cost becomes a real barrier to entry. The potential reward, however, will be large.

On the other hand, it is much easier to enter a labour intensive industry. The minimum scale of operation will be low, as will be the initial capital investment. The risk will be low, and not much capital will need to be raised. Cost will not be a barrier to entry, but the potential rewards are also smaller.

question

1

Economies of scale

Match the following examples of economies of scale with their classification.

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not right. Try again.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Capital and labour intensive

Which of the following industries would you expect to be capital intensive? (Select all appropriate answers)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Fruit growing and computer game development both require significant levels of labour and so would generally be described as labour intensive. Fruit growing and computer game development both require significant levels of labour and so would generally be described as labour intensive. Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

The very long run

So far we have looked at the short-run and the long-run. We now meet the very long run.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Very long run

Where changes in technology make major changes in costs possible.


Invention, innovation and technological change gives some firms a huge cost advantage in some industries, and brings into existence new industries in their own right.

A new invention, protected by patent, obviously gives its inventor a huge advantage. This is the way that the pharmaceutical industry works.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Patent

A document granting monopoly powers to the inventor of something for a period of time (up to 20 years) to allow it to recover its investment and make a reasonable return on it.


Within existing industries a smallish firm making a technological breakthrough can gain a cost advantage and become dominant. Look at the diagram below.

lrac4

Figure 1 Effect of technical breakthrough on competitive position of a firm

Innovation and invention has to be paid for, and research and development is an expensive exercise with no guarantee of success. Investing firms aim to protect and exploit their inventions, whilst others aim to obtain and use this research.

Major breakthroughs are few and far between, but yield big gains. They are costly.

Revenues

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Revenues - notes

Revenue is the income a firm obtains from the sales of its goods or services. Three terms must be understood:

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Revenue curves vary depending on whether price is constant at all levels of output (as in the case of a firm which is a price-taker), or falls as output increases (as in the case of a firm who is a price-setter). Look at Figures 1 and 2 below to see the difference this makes to the shape of the average / marginal revenue and total revenue curves:

ar_mr_tr_price_taker

Figure 1 Revenue curves - constant price (price-taker)

ar_mr_tr

Figure 2 Revenue curves - falling price (price-setter)

You have to be able to calculate revenue, in any form, from data, then draw and interpret curves. Time for an example, and for you to do some work again!

Output (units) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Total revenue ($ 000) 0 100 180 240 280 300 300 280 240 180 100


Plot this with output on the horizontal axis and revenue on the vertical axis. Look at it and then we will do some more calculations.

There is also a static version of this graph available.

Total revenue rose at first, reached a maximum, and then declined.

question

From the total revenue curve data above, now calculate the figures for marginal revenue and average revenue. Once you have had a go, click on the answer link below to check your calculations.

Answer - revenue calculations

Now, plot the marginal and average revenue curves from this data as well. Examine it. What does it tell you?

There is also a static version of this graph available.

Observation of the graph shows:

Profit

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Profit - notes

Within economics you will meet:

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

The definitions of supernormal and normal profit mean that profit on a diagram drawn by an economist shows supernormal profit only. Normal profit is included as an element of the ATC curve and arises where ATC = AR. Examine the following diagrams (we'll look at how to build these diagrams in more detail later on):

pc_snp_f

Figure 3 Firm in perfect competition - supernormal profit

monop_comp_sr_f

Figure 4 Monopoly - supernormal profit

This has to be compared with the accountant's definition of profit.

Accounting profit

The difference between revenue from sales and the costs incurred in making these sales, regardless of any credits given or taken.

Accountants deal in facts. They do not get involved with concepts such as normal profit. Governments tax accounting profit, not normal profit.

Why do firms try to make a profit?

Profit has many uses:

Profit is a driving force within business. It is an incentive for investors to invest. It lies behind all cost reduction exercises, as the aim of cost reduction is profit maximisation.

Combining revenue and cost curves

Now, some diagrammatical work. Let's combine the two examples developed in this section and the figures from the previous notes on costs. This gives us the data below.

Output (units) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Total cost ($ 000) 100 110 125 145 170 200 235 275 320 370 425
Total revenue ($ 000) 0 100 180 240 280 300 300 280 240 180 100
Profit ($ 000) -100 -10 55 90 110 100 65 15 -80 -190 -325
Marginal revenue ($ 000) 100 80 60 40 20 0 -20 -40 -60 -80
Marginal cost ($ 000) 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55


Now let's plot yet another graph. From the table above plot the marginal cost, marginal revenue and profit figures. You should get a graph looking like the figure below.

There is also a static version of the graph available.

See clearly that the profit is maximised when MC = MR. You can see this from the graph, but can confirm from the data that this is the case as well.

Profit maximisation - price taker


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Profit maximisation - price setter


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Alternative aims of firms


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Profit, sales and revenue maximisation


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

State owned companies

State owned (nationalised) companies or corporations are often thought to be 'good' because they are not profit maximisers. It is argued that they act 'in the public interest', avoid externalities, and minimise wasteful activities. However, this may not always be seen on examination of real nationalised corporations since many operate inefficiently and rely on government subsidies to survive, thus costing the taxpayer money.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\find_out.gif

Identify some state-owned companies in your own country. Quite often companies providing postal services, telecommunications and nuclear energy might feature in such a list. Since the collapse of many banks, resulting from a lack of adequate regulation in the banking sector, in the USA and across Europe, many are wholly or part-owned by their government who bailed them out financially. Research the background to some of the companies you have identified. You may find it most interesting, especially when you see how much of the tax payers money has been used!

Perfect competition

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Perfect competition - notes

Assumptions of the model

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\equality.jpgPerfect competition is considered as the ideal or the standard against which everything is judged. Perfect competition is characterised as having:

Equilibrium under perfect competition

In perfect competition, the market is the sum of all of the individual firms. The market is modelled by the standard market diagram (demand and supply) and the firm is modelled by the cost model (standard average and marginal cost curves). The firm as a price taker simply 'takes' and charges the market price (P* in Figure 1 below). This price represents their average and marginal revenue curve. Onto this we superimpose the marginal and average cost curves and this gives us the equilibrium of the firm.

pc_ind

Figure 1 Equilibrium of the firm and industry in perfect competition

Firms in equilibrium in perfect competition will make just normal profit. This level of profit is just enough to keep them in the industry and since profits are adequate they have no incentive to leave.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Normal profits

Normal profit is the level of profit that is required for a firm to keep the resources they are using in their current use. In other words it is enough profit to keep them in the industry. Anything in excess of normal profits is called abnormal or supernormal profits.


Any profit above normal profit is a 'bonus' for the firms, as it is more than they need to keep them in the industry. We call this supernormal (or abnormal) profit. However, this supernormal profit will be a signal to other firms and will attract more firms into the industry. If firms are making consistently below normal profits then they will choose to leave the industry.

Short-run to long-run - profits


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Short-run to long-run - losses


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Shut down price, break-even price

The break-even price in perfect competition is where normal profits are made and AR = P = ATC = MC = MR. This is shown in Figure 1 below.

pc

Figure 1 Perfect competition - break-even price


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Do perfectly competitively industries exist?

No 'perfect' perfectly competitive industries exist. Ironically, one of the closest today is probably the market for shares. However, as we mentioned before, it is still an important model as it provides a benchmark against which other markets can be judged. It can help in formulating appropriate policies to improve uncompetitive markets.

Efficient allocation of resources

Economists are concerned about the efficiency of markets, and ensuring that resources are allocated efficiently.

Perfect competition is considered to be efficient because:

The major assumption behind this analysis and evaluation is that firms cannot produce products cheaper if they were bigger. It assumes that there are no economies of scale available in the market.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Allocative efficiency

Allocative efficiency occurs when the value consumers put on the good or service equals the cost of producing the product or service. In other words, when price = marginal cost.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Productive efficiency

Productive efficiency occurs when output is achieved at the minimum average cost.


We can see from Figure 1 below that when it is in long-run equilibrium, perfect competition achieves allocative and productive efficiency as MC = MR = AC = AR. This means that they are maximising profits (MC = MR) but only making normal profit (AC = AR).

pc1

Figure 1 Long-run equilibrium - perfect competition

So, perfect competition looks good, but is it always so? Problems with perfect competition are:

Look at economies of scale. Some are always likely to exist. Financial economies apply - the better your reputation the cheaper the loans, bulk-buying economies are there as well. Economies of scale are there, like gravity. It is up to the firm to take advantage of them. Competition encourages their application and exploitation.

Perfect competition may well operate efficiently, as far as economists are concerned. The consumer, however, may get an ordinary product or service at a high price. Is it worth it?

question

1

Productive efficiency

At what point will the firm be productively efficient?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the condition for profit maximisation.No, that's not right. This would mean that the firm is making normal profit.Yes, that's correct. If MC=AC then the firm is producing at the minimum point of the average cost curve and is therefore productively efficient.No, that's not right. This would mean that the firm is allocatively efficient.
Check your answer

2

Allocative efficiency

At what point will the firm be allocatively efficient?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the condition for profit maximisation.No, that's not right. This would mean that the firm is making normal profit. No, that's not right. If MC=AC then the firm is producing at the minimum point of the average cost curve and is therefore productively efficient. Yes, that's correct. This would mean that the firm is allocatively efficient.
Check your answer

Monopoly and oligopoly

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Monopoly and oligopoly - introduction

Concentrated markets, ones where there are only a limited number of suppliers, behave differently to competitive markets. You are required to know about monopoly and oligopoly.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Monopoly

One or occasionally a few firms dominate the market. The others have to accept the market as established by the others. A perfect monopoly is when there is a single supplier. However, a firm gets monopoly powers as its market share edges above 25% (UK legal definition). Some industries are natural monopolies, such as water supply and basic power generation.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Oligopoly

Oligopoly is when a few suppliers who provide the same product dominate a market. Petrol companies and the soap and detergent industry are good examples. Each firm has to be concerned about what the others in the industry will do.


Governments are concerned about both of these types of competition. Economic theory suggests that as markets become more concentrated (the number of firms in the industry falls) they become controlled by the suppliers at the expense of the consumer. As we shall see, this is not always the case. Governments try to regulate (control) these industries.

As was seen earlier, the very size of the firms makes it difficult for others to enter the industry (the size of the firms acts as a barrier to entry). Sunk costs are high so potential losses are high. There is no great encouragement to enter the market however good a product the firm has.

Why do some markets become concentrated and others do not?

The simple answer is growth and economies of scale. Some firms are more efficient than others, and in some industries there are much greater economies of scale than others. This has led to the formation of a number of highly concentrated industries. Examples are the oil and petrochemical industry, the aircraft manufacturing industry, airlines, soft drinks and banking to name just a few. Follow the links below to see how each industry fits the characteristics of monopoly and oligopoly.

Oil and petrochemicals

Aircraft manufacture

Airlines

Soft drinks

Banking

All the above are examples of oligopoly. Examples of monopoly are few and far between. Many natural monopolies, often state owned, have been broken up (privatised) and artificial competition (usually with regulators to control the market) introduced. Examples are electrical power, gas and the telephone service.


www

More examples - web links

It is worth being aware of recent examples of monopoly and oligopoly and government policy towards them. You should also investigate monopoly and oligopoly situations in the country of your study. This can easily be done by doing an internet search using a search engine such as google. Most national newspapers across the world are also available on-line and have a key word search facility enabling you to explore with relative ease!

In the UK, the best bet is probably to do a search in the Biz/ed In the News archive. You can do this in the window below:

Try searching on terms like:

In many countries the definition of a monopoly may be broader than the view we take as economic theorists where we state that the firm is the industry! In the UK, for example, any firm that has 25+% share of the market would be subject to investigation as a monopoly.

N.B. When you are searching on more than one word, it is best to check the 'match exact phrase' box.


Growth and power

Why do firms want to grow?

As they get larger they get stronger. They start to eliminate competition, and start to gain control of the market. They move from being a 'price taker' in a situation of perfect competition towards being a 'price setter' (or price maker) in a monopoly situation.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Price taker

A price taker is a firm which cannot influence the price of the product on the market. If it puts its price above the one ruling in the market it sells little or none. Firms in perfect competition are price takers.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Price setter

A price setter (or price maker) is a firm that can determine or fix the price of the product on the market. It sets the price, but the quantity sold is determined by the demand curve.


Firms start to develop monopoly power as they grow and increase their market share.


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\key_terms.gif

Monopoly power

The power, or ability to influence a market, influence the survival of others, and establish the price. It enables it to increase profits.



If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

The model of monopoly

monopolyMonopoly, as a market form, is at the opposite end of the spectrum to perfect competition. In the literal sense, a monopoly exists when one single firm or a small group of firms acting together controls the entire market supply of a good or service for which there are no close substitutes. This is a situation of pure monopoly, which like the case of perfect competition, is rarely easy to identify in reality. Moreover, whether an industry can be classed as a monopoly will depend on how narrowly the industry is defined; for example, a city underground system (metro/subway) often has a monopoly on the supply of underground travel within the city, but does not have a monopoly on all forms of public transport within the city: people can also travel by bus, tram or overground trains.

Thus, in practice, less stringent definitions than 'single producer' tend to be used and economists focus instead on the degree of monopoly power which exists rather than absolute monopoly power. A firm, in the UK, may be regarded as being a monopolist if it controls 25 per cent or more of the total market supply of a particular good or service.

A market concentration ratio is used to measure the degree of concentration within a particular industry or group of industries. A commonly used ratio is the five firm concentration ratio that indicates the proportion of the industry's output produced by the five largest firms.

Theory of monopoly

The monopolist's demand curve

In our analysis of perfect competition, we showed how there is a distinction between the demand curve of the individual firm and that of the market as a whole - the existence of many firms each competing against each other means that each one has no influence over price, and has to take the price that is determined in the market through the intersection of the demand and supply curves. The demand curve for each firm is therefore horizontal: an infinite amount is demanded at one price, with nothing at all being demanded at a higher price and with the charging of a lower price being inconsistent with the goal of profit maximisation.

However, under monopoly there is only one firm in the industry; thus there is no difference between the demand curve for the industryand the demand curve for the firm. As the monopolist is subject to the normal law of demand, the monopolist's demand curve will be downward sloping so that to sell more, price would have to be lowered (see figure 1). In comparison to other types of market, the monopolist's demand curve is likely to be relatively inelastic as close substitutes may not be available if price is raised. Indeed, the availability or non-availability of close substitutes is one of the key factors determining the monopolist's power in the market.

monop_d

Figure 1 Monopolist's demand curve

The demand curve shown in Figure 1 presents the monopolist with a choice. The monopolist can either choose to make the price or the quantity, but cannot do both; for example, if the monopolist chooses to set a price of OP1, the market dictates that only a quantity of OQ1 could be sold; however, if the monopolist chooses to set a quantity of OQ2 to be sold, clearly the demand curve tells us that this could only be achieved at a price of OP2.

Marginal revenue and average revenue under monopoly

question

The table below assumes that the monopolist faces a normal demand schedule, and from this the revenue curves are derived. Try calculating the figures for total, average and marginal revenue and once you have had a go, follow the link to check your answers.

Output Price Total revenue Marginal revenue Average revenue
1 20
2 18
3 16
4 14


Total, average and marginal revenue answers

From the table two points can be seen:

a) As price has to be lowered to increase sales, marginal revenue is not equal to price as in perfect competition: the additional revenue gained from each extra sale is always less than price or average revenue, and thus the MR curve will always be below the AR curve in monopoly.

b) As price is identical to average revenue, the demand curve is also the curve relating average revenue to the quantity produced.

The information in this table can now be shown in diagrammatic form to show the relationship between the average and marginal revenue curves (figure 2).

ar_mr

Figure 2 Marginal and average revenue curves

Monopoly - profit maximisation


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Monopoly equilibrium


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Monopoly v. perfect competition


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Consumer and producer sovereignty

Because of the conditions of perfect competition - many buyers and sellers, perfect knowledge and freedom of entry - firms would be forced to produce those goods and services which consumers most wanted. Any firm or even group of firms not behaving in this way would be unable to survive for very long as the competitive pressures from those firms who were responding to consumers' wishes would soon drive them into extinction. From this point of view it could be argued that consumers are sovereign in as much that it is they who 'call all the shots'. However, as described previously, monopoly producers may well decide on which types of goods they are going to supply and at what prices, and then set about manipulating and moulding consumers' tastes, via their marketing activities, to match their pre-determined output plans - a situation in which the producer and not the consumer is sovereign.

question

1

Output levels - Monopoly

At which output level in the diagram below will the monopolist produce to ensure productive efficiency?

monop_output_level

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Profits are maximised where MC=MR.Yes, that's correct. This is the point where the firm will be productively efficient (minimum of average cost).No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be allocatively efficient (MC=price).No, that's not right. This is where total revenue will be maximised (MR=zero).No, that's not right. This is where the firm will make normal profits (AC=AR).
Check your answer

2

Output levels - Monopoly

At which output level in the diagram below will the firm produce to ensure allocative efficiency?

monop_output_level

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Profits are maximised where MC=MR.No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be productively efficient (minimum of average cost).Yes, that's correct. This is the point where the firm will be allocatively efficient (MC=price).No, that's not right. This is where total revenue will be maximised (MR=zero).No, that's not right. This is where the firm will make normal profits (AC=AR).
Check your answer

3

Monopolist - productive and allocative efficiency

A monopolist will be productively and allocatively efficient in long run equilibrium.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. A monopolist can be either productively OR allocatively efficient, but not both. If they choose to maximise profits, they will be neither.No, that's not right. The statement is false. A monopolist can be either productively OR allocatively efficient, but not both. If they choose to maximise profits, they will be neither.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

4

Perfect competition - productive and allocative efficiency

A firm in perfect competition will be both productively and allocatively efficient in long-run equilibrium.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. In long-run equilibrium in perfect competition MC=MR=AC=AR and this will ensure both productive and allocative efficiency.No, that's not right. The statement is true. In long-run equilibrium in perfect competition MC=MR=AC=AR and this will ensure both productive and allocative efficiency.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Economic efficiency in perfect competition


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Economic efficiency in perfect competition and monopoly


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

So can you now summarise the advantages and disadvantages of monopoly? Have a think about them, jot them down and then follow the link to compare your notes with ours.

Efficiency and market structure

We are concerned here with concentrated (monopoly and oligopoly) and competitive markets.

Competitive markets are considered to be statically efficient - both allocatively and productively. Dynamic efficiency is another matter. Because firms are all small, no one firm can afford research and development (R&D); it would have to be done on a collective or industrial basis. This has been done, but a number of problems arise over funding levies and charges.

Concentrated markets, on the other hand, are considered to be inefficient in the short-run. They are statically inefficient, even though their AC may be significantly lower than their smaller 'perfectly competitive' equivalent. The profit motive makes them strive to be more efficient, so they may invest in R&D and may be dynamically efficient

question

1

Monopoly vs perfect competition

In the diagram below, which area represents the level of consumer surplus under perfect competition?

monop_v_pc

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the consumer surplus once the monopolist has taken over the industry.No, that's not right. This is a part of the deadweight welfare loss when a monopolist takes over.Yes, that's correct. The consumer surplus is the triangle above the price line and under perfect competition, the price will be set where MC=AR.No, that's not right. This is the producer surplus under perfect competition.No, that's not right. This area does not represent either producer or consumer surplus.
Check your answer

2

Monopoly vs perfect competition

In the diagram below, which area represents the level of consumer surplus under monopoly?

monop_v_pc

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct. This is the consumer surplus once the monopolist has taken over the industry.No, that's not right. This is a part of the deadweight welfare loss when a monopolist takes over.No, that's not right. The consumer surplus is the triangle above the price line and under perfect competition, the price will be set where MC=AR.No, that's not right. This is the producer surplus under perfect competition.No, that's not right. This area does not represent either producer or consumer surplus.
Check your answer

3

Monopoly vs perfect competition

In the diagram below, which area represents the welfare loss if a monopolist takes over a perfectly competitive industry?

monop_v_pc

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the consumer surplus once the monopolist has taken over the industry.No, that's not right. This is part of the deadweight welfare loss when a monopolist takes over, but you also need to include area 5 as well.No, that's not right. The consumer surplus is the triangle above the price line and under perfect competition, the price will be set where MC=AR.No, that's not right. This is the producer surplus after the monopolist has taken over.Yes, that's correct. This area is the deadweight welfare loss if a monopolist takes over. The areas were previously part of consumer or producer surplus, but are lost once the monopolist takes over and limits output.
Check your answer

Monopolistic competition

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Monopolistic competition - notes


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Monopolistic competition in the short-run


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Monopolistic competition in the long run


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Oligopoly

By the end of this section you should be able to:

C:\Users\Paul\AppData\Local\Microsoft\Windows\Temporary Internet Files\Content.Outlook\3NXEDMZM\HL (2).gif

Oligopoly - notes

The nature of oligopoly / assumptions of the model

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\business management\student_packs\media_ops_management\images\waste_tap.jpg

Oligopoly is a market form in which there are only a few firms in the industry with many buyers; so market supply will be concentrated in the hands of relatively few producers, although an industry might still be said to be oligopolistic where several smaller firms existed alongside the few large firms that dominate; the wholesale petrol market provides a suitable example of the latter. The markets for cigarettes, ice cream, confectionery (candy), fizzy drinks (soda), high street banks, airline carriers, domestic appliances, soap powders and supermarket chains all provide good examples of oligopoly in many countries across the world.

Where the few firms produce an identical product, this is known as perfect oligopoly, and where, more commonly, the products are differentiated, this is referred to as imperfect oligopoly. The case of duopoly, where there are only two firms in the industry, is a special case of oligopoly.

However, the absolute number of firms in the market is less significant than the way in which they behave and the relationship between the firms that comprise the industry. In the case of the monopolist, for example, independent price and output decisions can be made, with the only consideration being the customer's reaction to the change in price. However, in oligopoly, where there is competition amongst the relatively few, each firm has to also try to assess the reaction of its rivals to a change in price, as each firm will occupy a sufficiently important position within the industry for its particular price and output decisions to have a significant impact on its competitors. If a firm in oligopoly is thinking of raising the price of its product, it has to assess whether its rivals will do likewise or keep price down in order to gain more custom. Oligopoly is characterised by interdependence between the firms that comprise the industry, and by reactive market behaviour.

Oligopoly has emerged as the most prevalent market form in the industrialised world. This can partly be explained by the existence of economies of scale, especially in manufacturing, encouraging the growth of large scale production; inevitably, as firms grow in size, the number of firms supplying the market falls, and hence the tendency towards oligopoly power. Moreover, once established, this power may be sustained by various barriers to entry, similar to those that exist under monopoly.

The importance of non-price competition

As we shall see from our discussion of oligopoly, an important feature of oligopolistic markets, i.e. ones dominated by a few large firms, is the tendency towards relative price stability. Lack of price movement will occur most obviously where firms collude with each other to collectively fix their prices, but it may also occur in a situation of what is known as non-collusive oligopoly, where no such price agreements exist; inderdependent firms may well come to the conclusion that there is no point in 'cutting each others throats' by engaging in price warfare in the longer term as this could be disastrous for all the combatants, although there may be a tendency towards occasional short bursts of price cutting. However, this absence of price competition does not necessarily mean an absence of competition: oligopolistic firms are likely to compete in a variety of non-price forms.

Non- price competition occurs where firms attempt to win a competitive advantage over their rivals by strategies other than reducing prices. Non-price competition inevitably involves product differentiation. Here, oligopolistic competitors try to create separate markets in which they can command consumer loyalty through the creation of actual or imagined differences in the goods or services they offer, which are essentially the same as their rivals. This is in contrast to perfect competition where the good on offer, perhaps an agricultural one, is homogeneous, and product differentiation is difficult e.g. one carrot is pretty much the same as another.

Product differentiation is extremely widespread amongst the whole variety of consumer goods and services that we buy e.g. washing machines, television sets, home computers, motor cars, washing powders, soft drinks, packaged holidays and financial services. These are all differentiated one from another in a variety of ways, including shape, size, quality and image.

Non-price competition may take a variety of forms, including:

Advertising and branding

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\business management\revision_pack\images\business.jpgThe creation of consumer loyalty to particular brands is mainly achieved through advertising, and it is in oligopolistic markets where branding, backed by extensive product promotion, is most prevalent. The markets for soap-powders, cereals, cars, confectionery and cosmetics provide a few notable examples.

The main aim of branding is to make particular goods, produced by particular firms, appear as if they have unique features which the products of competing firms do not possess. On occasions these features may be real, e.g. the distinctive quality of a BMW car or an Apple i-Pod. However, often the 'uniqueness' may only exist in consumers' minds, but a difference, real or imagined, in how consumers perceive branded products, may be sufficient to allow goods to be sold at very different prices e.g. well-known brands of soft drinks, sports-wear, bars of soap and shaving creams are all sold at higher prices than their 'own brand', or lesser-known, equivalents.

Thus, if successful, branding will reduce the degree of substitutability for the good, make its demand more inelastic, allow for higher prices and profits to be earned and enable the brand to become unassailable.

Moreover, the practice of multiple branding serves as a very effective barrier to entry of new firms e.g. go to any supermarket in the UK and you will see several brands of soap powders on the shelves, but these are mainly produced by just two firms, Unilever and Procter and Gamble - the costs of breaking into such a market would be formidable as any new entrant would have to compete against numerous brands of soap powder, requiring an enormous outlay on advertising; obviously if Unilever and Procter and Gamble only produced one brand each, the task of contesting the market would be made considerably easier.

Product innovation

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\circuit_board.jpgNon-price competition in oligopoly may also take the form of product innovation whereby rival firms attempt to gain a larger slice of the market by constantly seeking to improve the quality and/or style of their existing products, or by developing entirely new products. This innovation usually has to be backed by extensive research and development (R&D), and has the effect of causing rapid obsolescence of consumer durable goods, a renewable source of demand and certain decline for those firms unwilling or unable to engage in such innovation. Most car manufacturers, for example, are constantly in the process of changing the design and other features of particular models so as to generate new demand, and the few large firms that dominate the pharmaceuticals industry are locked into a perpetual struggle to develop new and better drugs. An interesting market to study in this respect is that of mobile phones, I-pods and I-phones!

Theories of oligopoly - non-collusive

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\scale_2.jpgThe various models of oligopoly can be classified under two main headings: non-collusive or competitive oligopoly and collusive oligopoly. We shall consider each in turn:

Non-collusive or competitive oligopoly

In this case, each firm will embark upon a particular strategy without colluding with its rivals, although there will of course still exist a state of interdependence, as possible reactions of rivals will have to be considered.

There are three broad approaches that might be adopted by firms in a situation of competitive oligopoly:

  1. Observe the behaviour of rival firms but make no attempt to predict their possible strategies on the basis that they will not develop counter strategies. This was the essence of the earliest model of oligopoly developed by Cournot as far back as 1838: each firm acts independently on the assumption that its decision will not provoke any response from rivals; this is not generally accepted nowadays as providing a useful framework in which to analyse contemporary oligopoly behaviour.
  2. Make the assumption that a given strategy will provoke a response from competitor firms, and assess the nature of the response using past experience. This is the basis of the kinked demand curve model, described below, in which it is assumed that any price cut by one oligopolist will induce all others to do likewise, whilst a similar price increase would not be matched.
  3. Formulate a strategy and try to anticipate how rivals are most likely to react, and be prepared with suitable counter measures.

This is the basis of game theory in which competition under oligopoly is seen as being similar to a game of chess in which every potential move must be regarded as a strategy, and possible reactive moves by opponents and subsequent counter-moves must all be carefully considered. The application of the theory of games to economics was first introduced in 1944 by J. von Neuman and O. Morgenstern. Game theory involves the study of optimal strategies to maximise payoffs, taking into account the risks involved in estimating reactions of opponents, and also the conditions under which there is a unique solution, such that an optimum strategy for two opponents is feasible and not inconsistent. A zero-sum game is one in which one player's gain is another's loss, and a non-zero-sum game is one in which a decision adopted by one player may be to the benefit of all. Look up 'The Prisoner's Dilemma'!


S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\www.gif

For some further resources on the Prisoner's dilemma, why not have a look at:

The kinked demand curve theory

In the discussion of non-collusive oligopoly, we shall focus our attention on the second of the three broad approaches identified on the previous page.


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Kinked demand curve - change in cost

In the discussion of non-collusive oligopoly, we shall focus our attention on the second of the three broad approaches identified on the previous page.


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Criticisms of the kinked demand curve theory

Cut-price competition (predatory pricing)

S:\triplea_resources\DP_topic_packs\economics\student_topic_packs\media_microeconomics\images\price_discount.jpgAlthough oligopolistic markets tend to be characterised by relative price stability in the longer term, occasionally short bursts of price warfare break out. This typically occurs when the dominant players attempt to defend and/or raise their market shares because the total level of demand in the market is insufficient to enable all to achieve their intended level of sales, and overcapacity results. Price cutting has the effect of reducing the profits of all the combatants in the short run, with consumers gaining the temporary benefit of lower prices.

However, the likely outcome is that the weakest firms, i.e. those with the highest costs, will be driven into bankruptcy, with a new era of relative price stability eventually emerging. If too many casualties are caused, consumers are likely to face greater monopoly power and possibly higher prices. Price wars have been experienced between supermarket chains in many countries. In the UK such wars have also featured in petrol station forecourts.

Theories of oligopoly - collusive

We saw in competitive oligopoly that firms can never be entirely sure as to how their competitors will react to any given marketing strategy. To overcome this uncertainty, firms may adopt a policy of reducing, or even eliminating, it by some form of central co-ordination, co-operation or collusion. Such collusion may occur where firms attempt to maximise their joint profits, by reaching agreement on their price, output and other policies, or where firms seek to prevent the entry of new firms into the industry so as to protect their longer run profits.

Forms of collusion

Formal collusion

The most common type of formal collusion is through the cartel; where a small number of rival firms, selling a similar product, come to the conclusion that it is in their joint interests to formally collude rather than compete, they may establish a cartel arrangement in which they agree to set an industry price and output which enables them to achieve a common objective. This is likely to involve the setting of agreed output quotas for each member in order to maintain the agreed price.

A successful cartel arrangement, from the point of view of the participating firms, would be one in which the cartel acts like a single monopolist to maximise profits of individual members. This is illustrated in figure 1 below.

prof_max_cartel

Figure 1 Profit maximisation for the cartel

This is the familiar monopoly diagram, with each curve representing the aggregated situation for all the firms in the cartel. In order to maximise profits, MC is equated with MR and a price of OP is set, with an output of OQ, which represents the potential level of sales. The allocation of this market quota between members could be decided by such criteria as geography, productive capacity or pre-cartel market share, or cartel members, having set a price of OP, could engage in non-price competition to each gain as large a slice of OQ as they can.

In practice, cartels may tend to be rather fragile and may not last for very long. This is because individual members may have an incentive to renege on the agreement by secretly undercutting the cartel price. The almost inevitable necessity to limit output to keep price high will tend to leave individual firms with spare productive capacity, and provide the temptation to increase profits by expanding output. Such an expansion would not only generate profit on the additional sales, but would also increase the profits on existing sales, as average fixed costs would fall as output expanded.

As the end result of successful collusion will be to create a situation similar to monopoly, with its consequent drawbacks and loss of economic efficiency, cartels are illegal in many countries, including the UK and the USA. Various cartels do, however, operate internationally, the most famous of which is OPEC, referred to earlier in your studies. Another example of an international cartel is IATA (The International Air Transport Association) which has sought to set prices for international airline routes. However, the experience of both these cartels has been one of price cutting amongst its members, particularly during periods of declining product demand and competition from non-members.

Informal or tacit collusion

The most usual method of tacit collusion is priceleadership. This occurs where one firm sets a price that is subsequently accepted as the market price by the other producers. There need be no formal or written agreement for this to happen; it is sufficient that firms believe this to be the best way of maintaining or increasing their profits. An example of price leadership is provided by the Ford Motor Company who has often been the first to raise prices in the car industry.

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\review.gif

Activity

Choose a particular market to study, e.g. the market for soap powders, chocolate bars, computers, ice cream or any other of your choice.

Investigate the degree and nature of competition in your chosen market and the implications of this for producers and consumers.

Price discrimination


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Equilibrium of the discriminating monopolist

pd_3rd_1

Figure 1 Equilibrium of the discriminating monopolist
The profit gain from price discrimination is (x + y) - z

In figure 1 there are two distinct markets, Market A and Market B. A third market, Market C, which is the combined market, is obtained by the horizontal summation of the individual AR and MR curves from A and B. Market A has an inelastic demand curve, whilst Market B has a more elastic demand curve. The gradient of the combined market demand curve will lie between that of A and B.

In the combined market, MC is equated with MR to give a single profit maximising price of OPc with an output of OQc, and a total profit equal to the shaded area z is earned. With a single price, this is the maximum profit that could be earned as the charging of a higher price would reduce demand and the area of profit, z.

However, total profits can be increased through price discrimination, with the total output OQc being sold at different prices in markets A and B. Price will always be higher in the market with a more inelastic demand as consumers will be less responsive to price changes.

As price discrimination only occurs where the differences in price are not associated with any cost differences, the combined market MC curve will also apply to markets A and B, and the output of each sub-market is therefore determined by equating MR in each market with the marginal cost of producing OQc units of output. Thus in figure 1, it can be seen that the marginal cost of production, OM, is projected back from the combined market as a horizontal line to enable the monopolist to find the equilibrium points Ea and Eb where MC = MR in each of the individual markets, A and B. Similarly the average cost of production, OC, is projected back from the combined market to determine the area of profit in markets A and B. As the level of profit is denoted by the amount by which AR exceeds AC, the areas x and y will represent the total profit for A and B respectively.

From the producer's standpoint, price discrimination will be a success if total profits increase as a result. In the diagram, it can be seen that Area x + Area y is greater than Area z, so the producer has succeeded.

Section 1.5 Theory of the firm - questions

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\HL.gif

In this section are a series of questions on the topic - theory of the firm. The questions may include various types of questions. For example:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to work through the questions.

Short-run - numerical

question

Question 1

A firm uses two variable factors of production in the manufacture of its product, labour and capital. It combines these with a fixed factor, land, to produce different quantities of output.

a) Is this firm operating in the short or long run?

The following data is available

Units of labour 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Output 10 25 30 25 20 15 10


b) When does the law of diminishing returns click in?

Question 2

A firm is planning to expand production by 300 units per hour. To do this it will have to either employ more labour, or bring in more special equipment. It has the following data available. Using this data only, advise the firm what it should do.

Cost of labour - £30 per hour
Productivity - 60 units per hour

Cost of equipment (hire charge) - £100 per hour
Productivity - 350 units per hour.

Question 3

You have asked the question, and the firm has supplied you with the following information:

Number of extra workers 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Expected total output 60 150 300 420 500 480 420


If more than 5 workers are employed, cost per worker will have to rise to £35 per worker. How does this information influence your case?

Question 4

The following information has been provided by the firm.

Anticipated cumulative increase in production requirements for next 6 periods

Period 1 2 3 4 5 6
Extra sales expected 300 400 550 700 1000 2000


How does this affect your advice?

Short-run - short-answer

question

Question 1

What is productivity and how is it affected by changes in the prices of factors of production?

Question 2

Explain the law of diminishing returns.

Question 3

All other things being equal, how would a firm decide what factors of production to use in its factory?

Question 4

Explain the term 'short-run'.

Question 5

Distinguish between diseconomies of scale and the law of diminishing returns.

Long-run - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain why all the firms in an industry within a single economy are not all the same size.

Question 2

Explain why firms are bigger in some industries than others.

Question 3

Explain how full exploitation of the benefits of economies of scale and the division of labour can result in a firm having to become international/multinational.

Question 4

An industry has 12 firms that operate within it. The market shares of the top 6 firms in 2002 are given below.

Firm A B C D E F
Market share (%) 24 21 16 12 8 6


Calculate the 3, 5 and 6 firm concentration ratios (the percentage market share accounted for by the top 3, top 5 and top 6 firms) for this industry.

Question 5

An industry has 24 firms that operate within it. The sales value of the top 6 firms in 2002 is given below.

Firm A B C D E F
Sales value ($m per year) 12.5 2.5 2.3 1.7 0.9 0.8


The industry is worth $24 million per year

Calculate the 3, 5 and 6 firm concentration ratios for this industry.

Question 6

Explain three economies and three diseconomies of scale that may affect a firm.

Question 7

Explain the term 'capital intensive' firm.

Question 8

Why do capital-intensive firms tend to be large in relation to the size of the market they are in?

Question 9

Explain the term 'minimum efficient scale of production'.

Cost theory - numerical

question

Question 1

Given the following table of costs:

Output 0 1 2 3 4 5
Total cost 50 80 100 150 250 750


Calculate the following:

(i) Fixed cost
(ii) Average cost of production
(iii) Variable cost per unit
(iv) Marginal cost

Plot all the cost curves on a single graph, and determine where diminishing returns sets in.

Question 2

A firm manufactures cars at its plant in Swindon. At a capacity of 100 cars per week it knows that it has an assembly cost of £5,000 per car. It needs to expand production and does a series of design and cost exercises. The results are summarised below.

Output (cars per week) 200 400 600 800 1,000 1,200 1,400 1,600
Assembly cost (£ per car) 3,000 2,500 2,300 2,200 2,000 2,400 2,800 4,000


(i) Plot the cost curve for the possible factory extensions.
(ii) Is this a short run or long run cost curve?
(iii) Explain why this curve is U shaped.

Cost theory - short-answer

question

Question 1

Why can fixed costs be considered as an entry fee?

Question 2

Distinguish between the very short-run, the short-run, the long run and the very long run.

Question 3

Explain the term marginal cost.

Question 4

How would you decide, looking at a firm's average cost curve, if it was capital or labour intensive?

Question 5

How and why do cost curves change with time?

Question 6

Explain how a firm's short run average total cost curve and marginal cost curve are related.

Question 7

Use diagrams to distinguish between the law of diminishing returns and economies of scale.

Interactive questions

The following table of data describes the operation of a firm over a limited output range, and is used for the next 5 questions.

Output 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Total cost 100 120 140 160 220 300 450 600 1,000 2,500 5,000


1

Fixed costs

The fixed costs for the firm are:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, well done. FC is the costs of 'output zero'. It is the entry cost to production in the short-run.No. Look again, but think first.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Average cost

The average cost of production when 5 items were made is:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes. Spot on. Answer. AC = TC/output. In this case, for 5 units, 300/5 = 60.No. Look again, but think first.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

3

Marginal cost

The marginal cost of the 7th unit is:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes. Spot on. It helps to know your definitions. Answer. Marginal cost of 7th = TC of 6th - TC of 7th = 600 - 450 = 150No. Look again, but think first.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

4

Diminishing returns

The firm exhibits diminishing returns to the variable factor from the:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes. Spot on. Diminishing returns = rising AVC. AVC is: at output 1=20, 2=20, 3=20, 4=30, 5=40, 6=58, 7=71. Constant returns up until 3 units and then diminishing.No. Look again, but think first.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

5

Variable cost per unit

The variable cost per unit when 4 units are made is:

a)
b)
c)
d)

Yes. Spot on. VC per unit = TVC / Output.

From table AVC is at output 3=20, 4=30, 5=40, 6=58. Now read off the answer. It is 30.

No. Look again, but think first.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Costs and cost curves - self-test questions

question

1

Cost calculation

A firm produces 200 units and the total cost of production is $4000. When they increase output to 220, the cost rises to $4200. What is the marginal cost?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. When output rises to 220, cost goes up by $200, but the marginal cost is the cost of one more unit.No, that's not right. The marginal cost is the cost of one more unit. This is the cost of two more units.Yes, that's correct. The marginal cost is the cost of one more unit (increase in cost of $200, from an increase in output of 20 equals $10 per unit).No, that's not right. Have you divided the increase in cost by the increase in output correctly?
Check your answer

2

Cost calculation

A firm produces 200 units and the total cost of production is $4000. When they increase output to 220, the cost rises to $4200. What is the average cost of producing 220 units?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the total cost, you need to divide by the level of output to get average cost.No, that's not right. This is the average cost of 200 units. No, that's not right. Have you divided by 200 units rather than 220 units?Yes, that's correct. Total cost of 220 units is $4200. Divide the total cost by the level of output and we get $19.10.
Check your answer

3

Cost calculation

A firm producing in the short run produces 200 units and the total cost of production is $4000. When they increase output to 220, the cost rises to $4200. When output rises to 240, the cost rises to $4100. The firm is experiencing:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. The firm is facing diminishing returns as the marginal cost is falling.No, that's not right. The firm is producing in the short run and so is not facing returns to scale.No, that's not right. The firm is producing in the short run and so is not facing returns to scale.Yes, that's correct. The marginal cost is falling and so the firm is facing diminishing returns to the variable factor.
Check your answer

4

Cost calculation

A firm produces 200 units and the total cost of production is $4000. When they increase output to 220, the cost rises to $4200. When the firm produces zero output, the cost is $1000. What is the fixed cost per unit when they produce 200 units?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the total fixed cost.No, that's not right. You seem to have done the calculation slightly wrong and are out by a multiple of 10.No, that's not right. This is the variable cost per unit.Yes, that's correct. Total fixed costs are $1000 and output is 200 and so fixed cost per unit is $5.
Check your answer

5

Cost calculation

A firm produces 200 units and the total cost of production is $4000. When they increase output to 220, the cost rises to $4200. When the firm produces zero output, the cost is $1000. What is the variable cost per unit when they produce 200 units?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the total variable cost.No, that's not right. You seem to have done the calculation slightly wrong and have perhaps divided by 220 rather than an output of 200.Yes, that's correct. This is the variable cost per unit. Total variable costs are $3200 and output is 200 and so variable cost per unit is $16.No, that's not right. This is the fixed cost per unit.
Check your answer

6

Types of costs

Match the following cost definitions to their type.

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not quite right. Have another go.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Revenues - numerical

question

Question 1

The following table of data represents a business in operation.

Output/sales 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Total revenue 0 100 180 240 280 300 300 280 240
Total costs 20 60 110 170 240 320 410 510 620


Determine:

(i) Average revenue
(ii) Marginal revenue
(iii) Profit
(iv) Marginal cost
(v) Average cost

Plot all the data on one graph and determine the profit maximising output. Confirm that at this output, MC = MR.

Question 2

A firm is selling 5 units of its product, and has the following cost and revenue figures.

Output/sales 0 1 2 3 4 5
Total revenue 0 200 350 450 500 500
Total costs 50 100 140 200 250 310


(a) Determine:

(i) the firm's average revenue and price
(ii) the firm's profit level.

b) Is the firm operating below or above its profit maximising output?

c) Determine the new total revenue and profit at the new level of output and sales.

Question 3

The following table shows the sales and revenue data for a firm selling its product.

Sales (units) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Price (£) 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40


Determine the firms TR, MR and AR over this range of output. Plot the firm's Revenue curves and show where the firm maximises its sales revenue.

Question 4

Distinguish between normal and supernormal profits.

Question 5

Who decides what level of profit is normal?

Question 6

Explain the difference between profit and money.

Question 7

What is a windfall profit?

Question 8

What is the difference between the average revenue of a product and its price?

Question 9

Why do businesses aim to make a profit?

Interactive questions

The following table of data represents a business in operation and is used for the following series of multiple-choice questions

Output/sales 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Total revenue 0 50 90 120 140 150 150 140 120
Total costs 10 30 55 85 120 160 205 255 310


1

Average revenue

What is the average revenue for the firm at an output of 6 units?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo. This is the average cost.No, this is nothing to do with 6 units.No. This is the total revenue, not the average.Yes, spot on. Answer is: Average revenue = price, so this is a simple one to start with. TR = 150 Sales = 6 AR = 150/6 = $25
Check your answer

2

Marginal revenue

What is the marginal revenue obtained from selling the 4th unit?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo. This is the price for 3 units.No. This is the price for 4 units.Yes, spot on. Answer: Definition - marginal revenue - the extra revenue from selling one more. Look at the calculations and the graph. You will see that the answer is $20.No. This is the TR when 4 are sold.
Check your answer

3

Profit maximising output

The firms profit maximising output is:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo. That is the maximum profit.No. One unit too few.Yes, spot on. Answer: equation MC = MR or look at the graph. Profit is maximised when the third unit is sold.No. That is the revenue maximising output.
Check your answer

4

Marginal revenue

What is the marginal revenue obtained from selling the 7th unit?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo. This is for the 6th.Yes, spot on. Answer: do the sums first and this type of question is easy. Guess, or try and do in your head, and you are in trouble, usually. Answer is a reduction of $10.No. This is for the 8th.No. This is the marginal cost of the 7th unit.
Check your answer

5

Revenue maximisation

The firm will maximise its revenue if it sells:

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, spot on. Answer: equation - revenue maximization when MR = zero. From the chart or the diagram - when it sells the 6th unit.No. Look again at the table, carefully.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Profit maximisation - short answer

question

Question 1

Why is profit maximised when MC = MR?

Question 2

What is the basic assumption that economists make about the objectives of private firms?

Question 3

Explain two other objectives a private firm might have.

Question 4

Why is it assumed that private firms ignore external costs?

Question 5

Explain the term 'satisficing'.

Revenue and profit - self-test questions

question

1

Revenue definitions

Match the following definitions to the appropriate type of revenue.

a)
b)
c)
Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not right. Have another go.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Revenue calculation

A firm is selling 100 units at a price of $25. However, to sell 110 units they need to cut the price to $24. What is the level of marginal revenue at this higher level of sales?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the extra revenue from selling the 10 extra units. The marginal cost is the cost of just one of these.No, that's not right. This is the total revenue of selling 110 units.Yes, that's correct. The marginal revenue is the difference between total revenue at 100 units ($2500) and total revenue at 110 ($2640) divided by ten to get the extra cost per unit.No, that's not right. This is the change in price, not the marginal revenue.
Check your answer

3

Revenue calculation

A firm is selling 100 units at a price of $25. However, to sell 110 units they need to cut the price to $24. What is the average revenue at 110 units?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. This is the average revenue at 100 units.No, that's not right. This is the total revenue of selling 110 units.No, that's not right. This is the marginal revenue, not the average revenue.Yes, that's correct. This is the average revenue of 110 units.
Check your answer

Perfect competition - numerical

Question 1

Examine the diagram that is given below, which represents a firm in a perfectly competitive market.

pc_shutdown1

What price would the firm require to:

(i) stay in the market in the long run
(ii) stay in the market in the short run
(iii) leave the market at once

Question 2

It is known that a firm is operating in a perfectly competitive market. Its situation is summarised in the table of data that follows.

Sales/production 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Total revenue 0 30 60 90 120 150 180 210
Total cost 10 40 60 70 80 100 130 160


What price would the firm require to:

(i) stay in the market in the long run?
(ii) stay in the market in the short run?
(iii) leave the market at once?

Is the firm in long or short run equilibrium?

Perfect competition - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain why a market for shares may be considered to approximate perfect competition.

Question 2

Is it possible for a firm in perfect competition to make supernormal profits?

Question 3

A firm in a perfectly competitive industry finds that it is trying to sell its product at a price above the prevailing market price. What can it do about the situation?

Question 4

What does the term 'freedom of entry and exit' to the market mean?

Question 5

Draw and explain the models for a firm and an industry in a perfectly competitive market in the long run.

Question 6

Will you find advertising in a perfectly competitive industry?

Question 7

It is an assumption of perfect competition that, in the long run, no firm makes supernormal profits, only normal profit. Does that mean that all firms in perfect competition make the same level of profit?

Question 8

Examine the data below, which is for 4 different firms.

Revenue data (£k) for four firms

Sales 0 1 2 3 4 5
A 0 10 20 30 40 50
B 0 30 60 90 120 150
C 0 50 95 135 170 155
D 0 40 80 120 160 200


All of the firms are in perfectly competitive industries except?

Question 9

Discuss the main problems with perfect competition.

Question 10

Why is the existence of perfect competition unlikely in the real world?

Perfect competition - self-test questions

question

1

Assumptions of perfect competition

Which of the following are assumptions we make about perfect competition? (Select all responses that are correct)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
Yes, that's correct. Well done. A large number of industries is not a condition of perfect competition as we are looking at just one industry. A lack of government intervention is not a condition and perfect competition requires perfect knowledge, not just reasonable access to information.No, that's not right. Have another go. A large number of industries is not a condition of perfect competition as we are looking at just one industry. A lack of government intervention is not a condition and perfect competition requires perfect knowledge, not just reasonable access to information.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Long-run equilibrium - perfect competition

Which of the following will be true when a firm is in long-run equilibrium in perfect competition? (Select all responses that are correct)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
a) Yes, that's correct. MC=MR means that the firm will be maximising profits. This is true in long-run equilibrium.a) No, that's not right. MC=MR means that the firm will be maximising profits. This is true in long-run equilibrium.b) Yes, that's correct. AC=AR means that the firm will be making normal profits. This is true in long-run equilibrium.b) No, that's not right. AC=AR means that the firm will be making normal profits. This is true in long-run equilibrium.c) Yes, that's correct. In long-run equilibrium the firm will make just normal profits.c) No, that's not right. In long-run equilibrium the firm will make just normal profits.d) Yes, that's correct. In long-run equilibrium MC=MR=AC=AR, and so MC=AR.d) No, that's not right. In long-run equilibrium MC=MR=AC=AR, and so MC=AR.e) Yes, that's correct. The average cost curve will just touch the average revenue curve and so is tangential.e) No, that's not right. The average cost curve will just touch the average revenue curve and so is tangential.f) Yes, that's correct. The MC curve will be upward sloping, not horizontal. It is the MR curve that is horizontal.f) No, that's not right. The MC curve will be upward sloping, not horizontal. It is the MR curve that is horizontal.
Check your answer

3

Long-run equilibrium - perfect competition

Which of the following will be true when a firm is in short-run equilibrium in perfect competition?

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
a) Yes, that's correct. MC=MR means that the firm will be maximising profits. This is true in short-run equilibrium.a) No, that's not right. MC=MR means that the firm will be maximising profits. This is true in short-run equilibrium.b) Yes, that's correct. AC=AR means that the firm will be making normal profits. This is NOT true in short-run equilibrium as the firm can be making supernormal profits in the short-run.b) No, that's not right. AC=AR means that the firm will be making normal profits. This is NOT true in short-run equilibrium as the firm can be making supernormal profits in the short-run.c) Yes, that's correct. In short-run equilibrium the firm can make supernormal profits.c) No, that's not right. In short-run equilibrium the firm can make supernormal profits.d) Yes, that's correct. In short-run equilibrium the firm can be making supernormal profits and so MC does not need to be equal to AR. This will only be true in long-run equilibrium.d) No, that's not right. In long-run equilibrium MC=MR=AC=AR, and so MC=AR.e) Yes, that's correct. In short-run equilibrium the firm can be making supernormal profits and so the AC curve can be below the MR (AR) curve. This will only be true in long-run equilibrium.e) No, that's not right. In short-run equilibrium the firm can be making supernormal profits and so the AC curve can be below the MR (AR) curve. This will only be true in long-run equilibrium.f) Yes, that's correct. The MC curve will be upward sloping, not horizontal. It is the MR curve that is horizontal.f) No, that's not right. The MC curve will be upward sloping, not horizontal. It is the MR curve that is horizontal.
Check your answer

4

Shut down price

Select appropriate options in the paragraph below to make up a suitable description of the shut-down price.

A firm may make a in the short run, providing is being covered and some contribution is being made to the fixed cost. If a firm is at least unable to cover its in the i.e. its day-to-day running costs, it will shut down immediately. In the the firm will need to at least break-even or make a if it is to survive.

Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not right. Have another go.Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

Monopoly and oligopoly - short answer

question

Monopoly and oligopoly - introduction

Question 1

Explain the difference between a monopoly industry and an oligopoly.

Question 2

Examine the factors that might give a firm a degree of monopoly power in a market consisting of several suppliers.

Question 3

What are barriers to entry? Why do monopoly suppliers spend so much time in establishing and maintaining them?

Question 4

Evaluate the following proposition:

'All monopolies are bad for the consumer and the economy, therefore they should be strictly controlled'.

Question 5

A car is a car! How do car companies compete effectively?

Question 6

Why do some industries, like the manufacture of aircraft engines, become highly concentrated, but the market for meals (restaurants) remains highly fragmented?

Question 7

Explain the differences between internal and external growth.

Question 8

Why do firms try to expand and grow?

Question 9

Explain the differences between a price taker and a price setter (maker).

Question 10

What factors affect the ability of a firm to expand?

Question 11

From where does a firm derive monopoly power?

Question 12

Many firms exist in the business world that operate in two sectors of the market, but very few operate in all three (primary, secondary and tertiary). Suggest why this is so.

Question 13

Describe the various ways in which firms compete to increase their market share

Question 14

Is such competition (see question 13) always in the interest of the consumers?

Monopoly - short answer

question

The model of monopoly

Question 1

Explain the meaning of the phrase 'the monopolist is constrained by the demand curve for the product'.

Question 2

Discuss the statement 'monopoly is always bad'.

Question 3

Discuss the statement 'monopoly is always inefficient'.

Question 4

Explain why, if a monopolist takes over a perfectly competitive industry and takes advantage of no economies of scale, then the monopolist will reduce the quantity available for sale and at the same time raise the price.

Question 5

Look at the data below, which gives the total revenue schedules for firms. Which company, A, B, C or D, is a monopolist?

Sales 1 2 3 4 5
Firm A 10 20 30 40 50
Firm B 100 190 270 340 400
Firm C 200 400 600 800 1000
Firm D 100 200 300 400 500


Question 6

Look at the data below, which gives the market shares for 4 different firms. Which company, A, B, C or D, is unlikely to have any monopoly power?

Company A B C D
Market share 65% 45% 25% 12%


The model of monopoly - self-test questions

question

1

Monopoly

Choose appropriate options below to make up an appropriate paragraph describing the characteristics of monopoly.

Under , can only exist in the , as in the new firms are attracted into the industry and the abnormal profits are competed away as the market supply curve shifts to the right and the market price falls. However, under new firms are unable to enter the market as there are various which are the very source of monopoly power. Thus a single firm may remain the only supplier, and supernormal profits may persist in both the short and long run; in monopoly, there is therefore no distinction between short and long run equilibrium.

Yes, that's correct. Well done.No, that's not quite right. Have another go.Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

2

Monopoly

Which of the following are true in monopoly? (Select all responses that are correct)

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
a) Yes, that's correct. The monopolist can set EITHER price OR output but not both.a) No, that's not right. The monopolist can set EITHER price OR output but not both.b) Yes, that's correct. The monopolist can make supernormal profits in both the short run and long run thanks to barriers to entry.b) No, that's not right. The monopolist can make supernormal profits in both the short run and long run thanks to barriers to entry.c) Yes, that's correct. The monopolist faces the market demand curve.c) No, that's not right. The monopolist faces the market demand curve.d) Yes, that's correct. Though a monopolist CAN make supernormal profits, these are not guaranteed.d) No, that's not right. Though a monopolist CAN make supernormal profits, these are not guaranteed.e) Yes, that's correct. Barriers to entry enable the firm to protect their supernormal profits in the long run.e) No, that's not right. Barriers to entry enable the firm to protect their supernormal profits in the long run.f) Yes, that's correct. The monopolist will always produce on the section of the demand curve that is elastic.f) No, that's not right. The monopolist will always produce on the section of the demand curve that is elastic.
Check your answer

3

Output levels - Monopoly

At which output level in the diagram below will the monopolist produce to maximise profits?

monop_output_level

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerYes, that's correct. Profits are maximised where MC=MR.No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be productively efficient (minimum of average cost).No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be allocatively efficient (MC=price).No, that's not right. This is where total revenue will be maximised (MR=zero).No, that's not right. This is where the firm will make normal profits (AC=AR).
Check your answer

4

Output levels - Monopoly

At which output level in the diagram below will the monopolist produce to maximise revenue?

monop_output_level

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
Please select an answerNo, that's not right. Profits are maximised where MC=MR.No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be productively efficient (minimum of average cost).No, that's not right. This is the point where the firm will be allocatively efficient (MC=price).Yes, that's correct. This is where total revenue will be maximised (MR=zero).No, that's not right. This is where the firm will make normal profits (AC=AR).
Check your answer

Economic efficiency - short answer

question

Economic efficiency in perfect competition and monopoly

Question 1

Explain the differences between allocative and productive efficiency.

Question 2

Why does perfect competition give efficient allocation of resources?

Question 3

What cannot be available in a perfectly competitive industry?

Question 4

Why, in spite of an efficient allocation of resources, may perfect competition not be a good thing for the consumer?

Question 5

Explain the differences between static and dynamic efficiency.

Question 6

Explain the differences between competitive and concentrated markets.

Question 7

What is meant by economic efficiency?

Question 8

Can monopolies ever be efficient?

Oligopoly - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain why price competition is rare in oligopoly.

Question 2

Explain the phenomenon of sticky prices in an oligopolistic market.

Question 3

Explain two models of an oligopolistic market.

Question 4

Explain why it is often considered that firms in oligopoly will collude over prices and form cartels and other forms of price fixing.

Question 5

Why is it difficult to break into an oligopolistic market?

Question 6

Discuss the various factors which a firm in an oligopolistic market is likely to take into account when deciding upon the price to charge for its product.

Price discrimination - short answer

question

Question 1

Explain how a motorcar manufacturer may practice price discrimination.

Question 2

What does a monopolist have to ensure does not happen if it wants the process of price discrimination to work?

Question 3

For price discrimination to work successfully the supplier will have to divide the market into at least two sections or segments. What characteristics do these segments have to have for the procedure to work?

Question 4

Who gains from price discrimination?

Question 5

Discuss how price discriminating monopolists stop products or services leaking from one market to another.

Theory of firm - essay

question

Question 1

(a) Explain why only normal profit may be earned in the long run in perfect competition

(b) Evaluate the view that the main goal of firms will always be that of profit maximisation.

The big giveaway

Read the article The big giveaway and then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the article in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Explain what is meant by the term 'freeconomics'.

Question 2

How can firms afford to make goods and services available for free?

Question 3

"Anderson's idea is that the internet, by reducing marginal costs, encourages businesses to make their money by offering free goods or services to an extent we have not witnessed before". Discuss the extent to which doing business over the internet reduces marginal costs.

Fixing it transparently

Read the articles Glassmakers fined record 1.4bn euros for price-fixing by European regulators and Europe fines glassmakers record 1.4bn euros then consider answers to the questions below. You can either read the articles in the window below or you can follow the previous link to read the article in a separate window.


question

Question 1

Explain what is meant by a cartel and how it is able to increase the profits of its members.

Question 2

Describe the market conditions are most likely to lead to the formation of a cartel?

Question 3

Evaluate two policies that can be used by governments to prevent price-fixing.

Question 4

Identify ways in which price discrimination can take place in an economy. Give examples from your own country/region.

Section 1.5 Theory of the firm - simulations and activities

S:\TripleA\Design\icons\small\HL.gif

In this section are a series of simulations and activities on the topic - Theory of the firm. These simulations and activities might include:





Click on the right arrow at the top or bottom of the page to move on to the next page.

DragIT - fixed cost curve

In the simulation below, drag the slider to see the impact of changes in fixed costs on the fixed cost curve.

If you would prefer to open this interaction in a new web window, then simply follow the link below:

question

1

Fixed cost changes

Select all the changes below that will result in the fixed cost curve shifting vertically upwards.

a)
b)
c)
d)
e)
f)
a) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. An increase in rent will increase fixed costs as rents do not generally change with the level of output.a) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. Rent is generally considered a fixed cost as it doesn't change with output. An increase in rent will therefore shift the fixed cost curve vertically upwards.b) This will shift the fixed cost curve downwards. Though insurance payments are generally considered a fixed cost, a decrease in insurance payments will shift the fixed cost curve downwards.b) This will shift the fixed cost curve downwards. Though insurance payments are generally considered a fixed cost, a decrease in insurance payments will shift the fixed cost curve downwards.c) This is a change in variable cost. Wages for production staff are generally considered variable costs as they increase with output.c) This is a change in variable cost. Wages for production staff are generally considered variable costs as they increase with output, so changes in wages will not affect the fixed cost curve.d) This is a change in variable cost. Fuel costs for delivery vehicles are generally considered variable costs as they increase with output.d) This is a change in variable cost. Fuel costs for delivery vehicles are generally considered variable costs as they increase with output, so changes in fuel costs will not affect the fixed cost curve.e) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. Security costs will generally be considered fixed costs and so higher security costs will shift the fixed cost curve vertically upwards.e) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. Security costs will generally be considered fixed costs as they don't vary with output and so higher security costs will shift the fixed cost curve vertically upwards.f) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. Business rates will generally be considered fixed costs and so higher business rates will shift the fixed cost curve vertically upwards.f) This will shift the fixed cost curve upwards. Business rates will generally be considered fixed costs as they don't vary with output and so higher business rates will shift the fixed cost curve vertically upwards.
Check your answer

DragIT - variable cost curve

In the simulation below, drag the slider to see the impact of changes in variable cost per unit on the variable cost curve. N.B. Please note that this is a variable cost curve with no diminishing returns to the variable factor.

If you would prefer to open this interaction in a new web window, then simply follow the link below:

question

1

Variable costs

An increase in raw material costs will shift the variable cost curve upwards.

a)
b)
That's correct. The statement is true. Raw materials are part of a company's variable costs, so an increase in raw material costs will shift the variable cost curve upwards.That's not right. The statement is true. Raw materials are part of a company's variable costs, so an increase in raw material costs will shift the variable cost curve upwards.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Variable cost changes

Which of the following will lead to the variable cost curve shifting downwards?

a)
b)
c)
d)
Yes, that's correct. Rents and software licences will generally be considered fixed costs and so not affect the variable cost curve. A reduction in energy prices will reduce production (and thus variable) costs.No that's not right. Rents and software licences will generally be considered fixed costs and so not affect the variable cost curve. A reduction in energy prices will reduce production (and thus variable) costs.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT -cost curves

In the simulation below, drag the sliders to see the impact of changes in costs on the various cost curves. N.B. Please note that the variable cost curve is shown with no diminishing returns to the variable factor.

If you would prefer to open this interaction in a new web window, then simply follow the link below:

1

Total costs

Choose appropriate words from each drop-down box to complete the description of total costs.

are the sum of fixed costs and variable costs at a particular level of output. are the cost of one more unit of output. In other words the increase in total cost from producing one more unit of output. are total costs divided by the level of output. There are three aspects of average cost: (ATC) which is total cost divided by the level of output, (AFC) which is total fixed cost divided by the level of output and (AVC) which is total variable cost divided by the level of output.

Yes, that's correct.No, some of the choices were not quite right. Try again.Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

Step-by-step - Short-run total cost curve


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

DragIT -revenue curve

In the simulation below, drag the sliders to see the impact of changes in price on the total revenue curve.

If you would prefer to open this interaction in a new web window, then simply follow the link below:

1

Total revenue curve

A fall in price will shift the total revenue curve upwards.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false as a fall in price will shift the total revenue curve downwards.No, that's not right. The statement is false as a fall in price will shift the total revenue curve downwards.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT - Revenue curves (1)

The demand curve for product Z is drawn below. Drag the orange dot, (located at the origin) to where you think is the correct price and quantity combination that would return maximum total revenue (TR) (as you do this the corresponding marginal revenue curve will appear).

question

1

Revenue curves

What is the price charged by the firm to generate maximum revenue?

The maximum revenue will be at a price of £14. The marginal revenue curve should be twice the slope of the demand curve. The demand curve crosses the axis at 14 units and so the MR curve should cross the axis at 7 units of output. This is the point where total revenue is at a maximum (any increase in output will mean negative marginal revenue and therefore a reduction in total revenue). At this level of output, the demand curve shows that the firm is charging a price of £14.Check your answer

2

Revenue curves

What will be the value of the total revenue received by the firm if they choose to maximise revenue?

Yes, that's correct. Well done. To maximise revenue the firm will sell 7 units at a price of £14 each. This will give them a total revenue of £98.No, that's not right. To maximise revenue the firm will sell 7 units at a price of £14 each. This will give them a total revenue of £98.Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

DragIT - Revenue curves (2)

A change in the firm's output represents a movement along the demand curve (AR) and a movement along the TR curve. A shift in the demand curve would cause the total revenue curve to shift too.

The diagram below shows the current demand curve and marginal revenue curve (AR1and MR1 respectively) for product Z. Demand for this product falls by two units at all prices.

(a) Click on the points where the demand curve crosses the two axes in order to construct the new demand curve.

(b) Now click on the two points where the MR curve crosses the two axes in order to construct the new MR curve.

You may like to check your answer.

question

1

Revenue curves

What is the new price charged by the firm to generate maximum revenue? (For the AR2 and MR2 curves)

The maximum revenue will, following the shift of the AR and MR curves, be at a price of £12. The marginal revenue curve should be twice the slope of the demand curve. The demand curve now crosses the axis at 12 units and so the new MR curve should cross the axis at 6 units of output. This is the point where total revenue is at a maximum (any increase in output will mean negative marginal revenue and therefore a reduction in total revenue). At this level of output, the demand curve shows that the firm is charging a price of £12.Check your answer

2

Revenue curves

What will be the value of the total revenue received by the firm following the shift of the demand curve to AR2 if they choose to maximise revenue?

Yes, that's correct. Well done. To maximise revenue the firm will sell 7 units at a price of £12 each. This will give them a total revenue of £72.No, that's not right. To maximise revenue the firm will sell 6 units at a price of £12 each. This will give them a total revenue of £72.Your answer has been saved.Check your answer

PlotIT - Profit maximisation

As we saw earlier, profit maximisation will occur for a firm where MC=MR. The following diagram shows the costs and revenues for a product Y over a range of output from zero to 80 units per week. Product Y is one of many products produced by the firm. The fixed costs associated with producing Y are £120 per week, £60 of which is normal profit.

slomanecon_c03_l05_5

What happens when the demand for a firm's product changes? How will this affect the profit maximising price and output? The following diagram is the same as the one above. It shows the cost and revenue curves for firm X in the production of good Y.

Now assume that a close competitor of product Y has dropped the price of its product. As a result demand for product Y changes by 15 units per week.

In the diagram below, click on the two points in turn where the new AR curve strikes the axes. Then do the same for the MR curve.

You may like to check your answer.

question

1

Shift in demand

Given the drop in demand faced by the firm, what is the new equilibrium profit maximising output and price? How much profit is the firm making at this equilibrium?

The new equilibrium output will be at 25 units (where MR = MC - profit maximising).The equilibrium price will be £12.00.

At this equilibrium, the firm will be making just normal profit, since AR = AC. In other words, supernormal profit is zero.

Check your answer

DragIT - Perfect competition

It should now be clear that the amount of profit or loss that the firm makes will depend on the market price.

In the diagram below drag the price up and down to see the impact of these price changes. Note that the vertical dotted line represents the profit-maximising or loss-minimising output, where MC = MR.

question

1

Perfect competition - equilibrium

When the firm in perfect competition is making supernormal profits, they are in long-run equilibrium.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. If supernormal profits are being made in perfect competition, this will attract new firms into the industry until the supernormal profits are competed away. In long-run equilibrium in perfect competition, there will therefore be just normal profits.No, that's not right. The statement is false. If supernormal profits are being made in perfect competition, this will attract new firms into the industry until the supernormal profits are competed away. In long-run equilibrium in perfect competition, there will therefore be just normal profits.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Perfect competition - shut-down point

If the price falls below the level of AVC the firm in perfect competition will cease production.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. A firm in perfect competition will cease production when price falls below average variable cost as they will make less of a loss if they cease production and pay just their fixed costs.No, that's not right. The statement is true. A firm in perfect competition will cease production when price falls below average variable cost as they will make less of a loss if they cease production and pay just their fixed costs.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

Step-by-step - perfect competition, short-run supernormal profit


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - perfect competition, short-run losses


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - perfect competition, firm and industry


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

DragIT - Monopoly (1)

The amount of profit that the firm under monopoly makes depends on (a) demand, and hence the position of the AR and MR curves; (b) costs, and hence the position of the AC and MC curves.

In the diagram below, drag the average and marginal cost curves to see the impact that changes in cost will have on the firm's profitability.

question

1

Monopoly equilibrium

If AC is greater than AR where MC=MR, then the monopolist will be making a loss.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is true. If the monopoly is maximising profits (MC=MR) and the average cost is great than the price (average revenue), then the firm will be making a loss. Try it on the above diagram.No, that's not right. The statement is true. If the monopoly is maximising profits (MC=MR) and the average cost is great than the price (average revenue), then the firm will be making a loss. Try it on the above diagram.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

2

Monopoly - equilibrium

Where the AC is tangential to the AR curve the monopolist will be making supernormal profit.

a)
b)
Yes, that's correct. The statement is false. If the AC is tangential to the AR (just touching it), then the monopolist is making just normal profit.No, that's not right. The statement is false. If the AC is tangential to the AR (just touching it), then the monopolist is making just normal profit.Your answer has been saved.
Check your answer

DragIT - Monopoly (2)

The diagram below shows the profit-maximising price and output of a firm facing a downward-sloping demand curve. Show the effect on price and output of a rise in demand by dragging the AR and MR curves. Do this by clicking on the 'MR1' label and dragging it vertically up and down.

Now click on the top of the MC curve and, by making it steeper or flatter, show the effect on Q and P after the AR curve has been dragged to the right.

Step-by-step - monopoly


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

DragIT - Welfare loss under monopoly

Deadweight welfare loss depends on the degree of monopoly power, which in turn depends on the price elasticity of demand for the monopoly's product.

To see how the deadweight welfare loss changes as the price elasticity of demand changes, drag the handle at the end of the AR curve (i.e. the demand curve) in the diagram below. The deadweight welfare loss is represented by the shaded area. As demand becomes more elastic, so the deadweight welfare loss decreases.

Step-by-step - monopolistic competition, short-run


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

Step-by-step - monopolistic competition, short-run


If you would prefer to view this interaction in a new web window, then please follow the link below:

hl_stop